IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/f/c/ppi253.html
   My authors  Follow this author

Jonathan James Pincus

Citations

Many of the citations below have been collected in an experimental project, CitEc, where a more detailed citation analysis can be found. These are citations from works listed in RePEc that could be analyzed mechanically. So far, only a minority of all works could be analyzed. See under "Corrections" how you can help improve the citation analysis.

Working papers

  1. Zachary Grossman & Jonathan Pincus & Perry Shapiro & Duygu Yengin, 2018. "Second-Best Mechanisms for Land Assembly and Hold-Out Problems," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2018-14, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Zillante, Artie & Read, Dustin C. & Seiler, Michael J., 2020. "Assembling land for urban revitalization in the presence of linchpin parcels and information asymmetries: An experimental investigation," Land Use Policy, Elsevier, vol. 99(C).
    2. Chaturvedi, Rakesh, 2023. "Cost of efficiency in trading perfect complements," Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 230(C).
    3. Tsai, I-Chun & Wang, Wen-Kai, 2022. "The value of land redevelopment in different types of properties: Considering the effect of hold-out problems on the development probability," Land Use Policy, Elsevier, vol. 119(C).
    4. Soumendu Sarkar & Dhritiman Gupta, 2022. "Bargaining for Assembly," Working papers 319, Centre for Development Economics, Delhi School of Economics.
    5. Soumendu Sarkar, 2022. "Strategyproof and Budget Balanced Mechanisms for Assembly," Working papers 320, Centre for Development Economics, Delhi School of Economics.
    6. Soumendu Sarkar, 2022. "Optimal mechanism for land acquisition," Review of Economic Design, Springer;Society for Economic Design, vol. 26(1), pages 87-116, March.
    7. Hagen, Martin, 2023. "Collusion-proof mechanisms for multi-unit procurement," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 138(C), pages 281-298.
    8. Uyanik, Metin & Yengin, Duygu, 2023. "Expropriation power in private dealings: Quota rule in collective sales," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 141(C), pages 548-580.

  2. Jonathan Pincus, 2017. "Grattan Institute's Case for Sugar Tax is Not Proven," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2017-04, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. I.Fazrakhmanov & M. Lukyanova & V. Kovshov & A. Farrakhetdinova & J. Putyatinskaya, 2018. "Economic Assessment and Strategic Potential of Agro Industries: The Case of Sugar Industry," European Research Studies Journal, European Research Studies Journal, vol. 0(4), pages 239-254.
    2. Sainsbury, Emma & Magnusson, Roger & Thow, Anne-Marie & Colagiuri, Stephen, 2020. "Explaining resistance to regulatory interventions to prevent obesity and improve nutrition: A case-study of a sugar-sweetened beverages tax in Australia," Food Policy, Elsevier, vol. 93(C).
    3. Julio C. Arteaga & Daniel Flores & Edgar Luna, 2021. "The effect of a soft drink tax in Mexico: evidence from time series industry data," Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, vol. 65(2), pages 349-366, April.
    4. Peter Lloyd & Donald MacLaren, 2019. "Should We Tax Sugar and If So How?," Australian Economic Review, The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, vol. 52(1), pages 19-40, March.

  3. Jonathan Pincus & Henry Ergas, 2013. "Have Mining Royalties Been Beneficial to Australia?," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2013-10, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Paredes, Dusan & Rivera, Nathaly M., 2017. "Mineral taxes and the local public goods provision in mining communities," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 53(C), pages 328-339.
    2. Fogarty, James J. & Sagerer, Simon, 2016. "Exploration externalities and government subsidies: The return to government," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 47(C), pages 78-86.
    3. Drew, Joseph & Dollery, Brian Edward & Blackwell, Boyd Dirk, 2018. "A square deal? Mining costs, mining royalties and local government in New South Wales, Australia," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 55(C), pages 113-122.
    4. Oyarzo, Mauricio & Paredes, Dusan, 2021. "The impact of mining taxes on public education: Evidence for mining municipalities in Chile," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 70(C).
    5. Valle de Souza, Simone & Dollery, Brian & Blackwell, Boyd, 2018. "An empirical analysis of mining costs and mining royalties in Queensland local government," Energy Economics, Elsevier, vol. 74(C), pages 656-662.

  4. Jonathan Pincus, 2013. "The Wellbeing of the Australian People: Comments on the TreasuryÂ’s Framework," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2013-03, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Jonathan Pincus, 2013. "The Power to Tax, 33 Years Later," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 20(2), pages 89-104.

  5. Henry Ergas & Jonathan Pincus, 2012. "Modelling the Excess Burden of Royalties," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2012-03, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Jonathan Pincus, 2012. "The Treasury-KPMG Econtech Modelling of the Excess Burden of Mining Taxation: Some Doubts," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 19(2), pages 23-38.
    2. Jonathan Pincus & Henry Ergas, 2013. "Have Mining Royalties Been Beneficial to Australia?," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2013-10, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

  6. Grossman, Zachary & Pincus, Jonathan & Shapiro, Perry, 2010. "A Second-Best Mechanism for Land Assembly," University of California at Santa Barbara, Economics Working Paper Series qt1dn8g6vk, Department of Economics, UC Santa Barbara.

    Cited by:

    1. Sarkar, Soumendu, 2018. "Convergence of VCG mechanism to ex-post budget balance in a model of land acquisition," Mathematical Social Sciences, Elsevier, vol. 93(C), pages 37-46.
    2. Matt Van Essen, 2013. "Regulating the Anticommons: Insights from Public‐Expenditure Theory," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 80(2), pages 523-539, October.
    3. Usha Sridhar & Sridhar Mandyam, 2013. "A Group Utility Maximizer Mechanism for Land Assembly," The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Springer, vol. 47(3), pages 466-488, October.
    4. Scott Duke Kominers & E. Glen Weyl, 2012. "Holdout in the Assembly of Complements: A Problem for Market Design," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 102(3), pages 360-365, May.
    5. Soumendu Sarkar, 2017. "Mechanism design for land acquisition," International Journal of Game Theory, Springer;Game Theory Society, vol. 46(3), pages 783-812, August.
    6. Zakharenko, Roman, 2021. "Optimal compulsion for private assembly of property," Regional Science and Urban Economics, Elsevier, vol. 88(C).
    7. Chaturvedi, Rakesh, 2020. "Fairness and partial coercion in land assembly," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 120(C), pages 325-335.

  7. Jonathan Pincus & Perry Shapiro, 2008. "Efficiency and Equity in the Use of Eminent Domain, with Local Externalies," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2008-09, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Lozano-Gracia, Nancy & Young, Cheryl & Lall, Somik V. & Vishwanath, Tara, 2013. "Leveraging land to enable urban transformation : lessons from global experience," Policy Research Working Paper Series 6312, The World Bank.

  8. Jonathan Pincus & Perry Shapiro, 2008. "Between Forced Resumption and Voluntary Sale: A Mechanism for the Collective Sale or Transfer of Irrigation Water," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2008-07, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Grossman, Zachary & Pincus, Jonathan & Shapiro, Perry & Yengin, Duygu, 2019. "Second-best mechanisms for land assembly and hold-out problems," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 175(C), pages 1-16.
    2. Crase, Lin & O'Keefe, Sue & Dollery, Brian, 2009. "Water Buy-Back in Australia: Political, Technical and Allocative Challenges," 2009 Conference (53rd), February 11-13, 2009, Cairns, Australia 47640, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society.

  9. Geoffrey Brennan & Jonathan Pincus, 1998. "Is Vertical Fiscal Imbalance so Inefficient? or, The Flypaper Effect is not an Anomaly," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 1998-06, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Santiago Lago, "undated". "Descentralización fiscal, nivelación interterritorial y externalidades presupuestarias: Perspectiva analítica y reflexiones para el caso espanol," Studies on the Spanish Economy 130, FEDEA.
    2. Evgeny N. Timushev, 2017. "Flypaper Effect: Causes and Demonstration in the Budgetary System of Russia," Finansovyj žhurnal — Financial Journal, Financial Research Institute, Moscow 125375, Russia, issue 5, pages 60-70, October.

  10. P.W. Miller & J. Pincus, 1997. "Financing Higher Education in Australia: The case for superhecs," Economics Discussion / Working Papers 97-15, The University of Western Australia, Department of Economics.

    Cited by:

    1. Peter Karmel, 2001. "Public Policy and Higher Education," Australian Journal of Management, Australian School of Business, vol. 26(1_suppl), pages 123-143, August.
    2. Jonathan Pincus, 1998. "Is the Treasury subsidising Australian Undergraduates? or, Investing in Higher Education," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 1998-15, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

  11. Geoffrey Brennan & Jonathan Pincus, 1995. "A Minimalist Model of Federal Grants and Flypaper Effects," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 1995-01, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Baicker, Katherine, 2001. "Government decision-making and the incidence of federal mandates," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 82(2), pages 147-194, November.
    2. Kakamu, Kazuhiko & Yunoue, Hideo & Kuramoto, Takashi, 2014. "Spatial patterns of flypaper effects for local expenditure by policy objective in Japan: A Bayesian approach," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 37(C), pages 500-506.
    3. Yihua Yu & Jing Wang & Xi Tian, 2016. "Identifying the Flypaper Effect in the Presence of Spatial Dependence: Evidence from Education in China's Counties," Growth and Change, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 47(1), pages 93-110, March.
    4. Brian Dollery & Andrew Worthington, 1999. "Fiscal Illusion at the Local Level: An Empirical Test Using Australian Municipal Data," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 75(1), pages 37-48, March.
    5. Yongqiu Wu & Yi Huang & Jing Zhao & Yanping Pu, 2017. "Transfer payment structure and local government fiscal efficiency: evidence from China," China Finance and Economic Review, Springer, vol. 5(1), pages 1-15, December.
    6. Sergey Sinelnikov & Pavel Kadochnikov & Ilya Trunin (ed.), 2006. "Fiscal Federalism in Russia: Soft Budget Constraints of Regional Governments," Books, Gaidar Institute for Economic Policy, edition 1, number 4, November.
    7. Craig Brett & Christina Tardif, 2008. "The Grants are Falling! The Grants are Falling! How Municipal Governments Changed Taxes in Response to Provincial Support in New Brunswick, 1983­2003," Canadian Public Policy, University of Toronto Press, vol. 34(4), pages 441-456, December.
    8. Cont, Walter & Porto, Alberto, 2014. "Personal and regional redistribution through public finance in a federal setting," The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Elsevier, vol. 54(4), pages 563-578.
    9. Mark Kattenberg & Wouter Vermeulen, 2018. "The stimulative effect of an unconditional block grant on the decentralized provision of care," International Tax and Public Finance, Springer;International Institute of Public Finance, vol. 25(1), pages 166-199, February.
    10. Robin Boadway & Michael Keen, 1996. "Efficiency and the optimal direction of federal-state transfers," International Tax and Public Finance, Springer;International Institute of Public Finance, vol. 3(2), pages 137-155, May.
    11. Becerra, Ligia Melo, 2004. "Intergovernmental fiscal relations : the Colombian case," Economics PhD Theses 0304, Department of Economics, University of Sussex Business School.
    12. Sergey Sinelnikov & Pavel Kadochnikov & Ilya Trunin & Sergey Chetverikov & Marianne Vigneault, 2006. "Fiscal Federalism in Russia: Soft Budget Constraints of Regional Governments," Published Papers 47, Gaidar Institute for Economic Policy, revised 2012.
    13. Mark Kattenberg & Wouter Vermeulen, 2016. "The Stimulative Effect of an Unconditional Block Grant on the Decentralized Provision of Care," SERC Discussion Papers 0209, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.

  12. Jonathan Pincus, 1991. "The Australian Constitution: What Should Economists Do?," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 1991-09, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

    Cited by:

    1. Zvelindovsky, Andrei V. & Bedeaux, Dick, 1995. "Thermal hydrodynamic fluctuations of polymer globules," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 222(1), pages 87-104.

Articles

  1. Grossman, Zachary & Pincus, Jonathan & Shapiro, Perry & Yengin, Duygu, 2019. "Second-best mechanisms for land assembly and hold-out problems," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 175(C), pages 1-16.
    See citations under working paper version above.
  2. Jonathan Pincus, 2018. "Grattan Institute's Case for Sugar Tax Is Not Proven," Australian Economic Review, The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, vol. 51(1), pages 41-51, March.
    See citations under working paper version above.
  3. Henry Ergas & Jonathan Pincus, 2014. "Have Mining Royalties Been Beneficial to Australia?," Economic Papers, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 33(1), pages 13-28, March.
    See citations under working paper version above.
  4. Jonathan Pincus, 2012. "The Treasury-KPMG Econtech Modelling of the Excess Burden of Mining Taxation: Some Doubts," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 19(2), pages 23-38.

    Cited by:

    1. Jonathan Pincus & Henry Ergas, 2013. "Have Mining Royalties Been Beneficial to Australia?," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2013-10, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.
    2. P Sivashankar & RMPS Rathnayake & Maneka Jayasinghe & Christine Smith, 2017. "Incidence of value added taxation on inequality: Evidence from Sri Lanka," Discussion Papers in Economics economics:201704, Griffith University, Department of Accounting, Finance and Economics.

  5. Kaniyal, Ashok A. & Nathan, Graham J. & Pincus, Jonathan J., 2012. "The potential role of data-centres in enabling investment in geothermal energy," Applied Energy, Elsevier, vol. 98(C), pages 458-466.

    Cited by:

    1. Daniilidis, Alexandros & Saeid, Sanaz & Doonechaly, Nima Gholizadeh, 2021. "The fault plane as the main fluid pathway: Geothermal field development options under subsurface and operational uncertainty," Renewable Energy, Elsevier, vol. 171(C), pages 927-946.
    2. Wang, Fu & Deng, Shuai & Zhao, Jun & Wang, Junyao & Sun, Taiwei & Yan, Jinyue, 2017. "Performance and economic assessments of integrating geothermal energy into coal-fired power plant with CO2 capture," Energy, Elsevier, vol. 119(C), pages 278-287.
    3. Siriwardana, Jayantha & Jayasekara, Saliya & Halgamuge, Saman K., 2013. "Potential of air-side economizers for data center cooling: A case study for key Australian cities," Applied Energy, Elsevier, vol. 104(C), pages 207-219.

  6. Paul W. Miller & Jonathan J. Pincus, 2010. "Introduction," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 86(s1), pages 1-1, September.

    Cited by:

    1. Pietro Masina, 2010. "Vietnam between developmental state and neoliberalism: the case of the industrial sector," Working Papers 1007, c.MET-05 - Centro Interuniversitario di Economia Applicata alle Politiche per L'industria, lo Sviluppo locale e l'Internazionalizzazione.
    2. Erlend Krogstad, 2007. "The Post-Washington Consensus: Brand New Agenda or Old Wine in a New Bottle?," Challenge, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 50(2), pages 67-85.
    3. Francisco Panizza, 2005. "Unarmed Utopia Revisited: The Resurgence of Left‐of‐Centre Politics in Latin America," Political Studies, Political Studies Association, vol. 53(4), pages 716-734, December.
    4. Mavroudeas, Stavros & Papadatos, Fanis, 2007. "Reform, Reform the Reforms or Simply Regression? The Washington Consensus' and its Critics," MPRA Paper 19735, University Library of Munich, Germany.

  7. Henry Ergas & Mark Harrison & Jonathan Pincus, 2010. "Some Economics of Mining Taxation," Economic Papers, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 29(4), pages 369-383, December.

    Cited by:

    1. Bayari, Celal, 2015. "Economic Geography of the Australian Mining Industry," MPRA Paper 102831, University Library of Munich, Germany, revised 25 Jul 2015.
    2. Jonathan Pincus, 2012. "The Treasury-KPMG Econtech Modelling of the Excess Burden of Mining Taxation: Some Doubts," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 19(2), pages 23-38.
    3. Jonathan Pincus & Henry Ergas, 2013. "Have Mining Royalties Been Beneficial to Australia?," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2013-10, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.
    4. Jonathan Pincus, 2013. "The Power to Tax, 33 Years Later," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 20(2), pages 89-104.
    5. Freebairn, John, 2012. "Mining booms and government budgets," Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, vol. 56(2), pages 1-21.
    6. Eduardo A. Haddad & Jaime Bonet-Morón & Gerson Javier Pérez-Valbuena, 2022. "Impacto regional de las regalías en Colombia," Documentos de Trabajo Sobre Economía Regional y Urbana 20125, Banco de la República, Economía Regional.
    7. Hogan, Lindsay, 2012. "Non-renewable resource taxation: policy reform in Australia," Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, vol. 56(2), pages 1-16.
    8. Vining, Aidan R. & Moore, Mark A., 2017. "Potash ownership and extraction: Between a rock and a hard place in Saskatchewan," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 54(C), pages 71-80.
    9. Drew, Joseph & Dollery, Brian Edward & Blackwell, Boyd Dirk, 2018. "A square deal? Mining costs, mining royalties and local government in New South Wales, Australia," Resources Policy, Elsevier, vol. 55(C), pages 113-122.
    10. Boyd Blackwell & Brian Dollery, 2013. "Resource Taxation and Remote Aboriginal Expenditure," Economic Papers, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 32(3), pages 360-382, September.
    11. Valle de Souza, Simone & Dollery, Brian & Blackwell, Boyd, 2018. "An empirical analysis of mining costs and mining royalties in Queensland local government," Energy Economics, Elsevier, vol. 74(C), pages 656-662.
    12. Cullen, Ross, 2014. "The good oil. State roles in Norwegian petroleum sector," 2014 Conference (58th), February 4-7, 2014, Port Macquarie, Australia 165816, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society.
    13. Mr. James L. Smith, 2012. "Issues in Extractive Resource Taxation: A Review of Research Methods and Models," IMF Working Papers 2012/287, International Monetary Fund.

  8. Jonathan Pincus, 2009. "Reflection on Microeconomic Policy Frameworks in Australia, and a Suggestion about Fairness," Australian Economic Review, The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, vol. 42(2), pages 121-130, June.

    Cited by:

    1. Jonathan Pincus, 2014. "Public Choice Theory had Negligible Effect on Australian Microeconomic Policy, 1970s to 2000s," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2014-02, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.

  9. Jonathan Pincus & Perry Shapiro, 2008. "Between Forced Resumption And Voluntary Sale: A Mechanism For The Collective Sale Or Transfer Of Irrigation Water," Economic Papers, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 27(4), pages 303-314, December.
    See citations under working paper version above.
  10. Geoffrey Brennan & Jonathan J. Pincus, 2004. "Fiscal Equalisation: Some Questions of Design," Rivista di Politica Economica, SIPI Spa, vol. 94(4), pages 79-104, July-Augu.

    Cited by:

    1. Brennan Geoffrey & Pincus Jonathan J., 2010. "Fiscal Equity In Federal Systems," Review of Law & Economics, De Gruyter, vol. 6(3), pages 347-363, December.

  11. Jonathan Pincus, 2000. "Do We Know Federal Treasury Overspends on Undergraduates?," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 7(3), pages 277-288.

    Cited by:

    1. Bruce Chapman & Tony Salvage, 2001. "Australian Postgraduate Financing Options," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 8(4), pages 349-364.
    2. Roger Dean, 2002. "Economic and Social Benefits of Universities: Policy Implications," Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, Australian National University, College of Business and Economics, School of Economics, vol. 9(3), pages 275-288.

  12. Brennan, G. & Pincus, J. J., 1996. "A minimalist model of federal grants and flypaper effects," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 61(2), pages 229-246, August.
    See citations under working paper version above.
  13. Geoffrey Brennan & Jonathan Pincus, 1987. "Rational Actor Theory in Politics: A Critical Review of John Quiggin," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 63(1), pages 22-32, March.

    Cited by:

    1. Gebhard Kirchgässner, 2005. "The Weak Rationality Principle in Economics," CESifo Working Paper Series 1410, CESifo.
    2. Quiggin, John, 2004. "The Y2K Scare: Causes, Costs and Cures," Risk and Sustainable Management Group Working Papers 151503, University of Queensland, School of Economics.
    3. Martin, William J., 1990. "Public Choice Theory And Australian Agricultural Policy Reform," Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, vol. 34(3), pages 203-203, December.
    4. Coggins, Jay S., 1994. "Trade and the Food Industries: Public and Social Choice," Staff Papers 200577, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics.

  14. Brennan, Geoffrey & Pincus, Jonathan J, 1983. "Government Expenditure Growth and Resource Allocation: The Nebulous Connection," Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford University Press, vol. 35(3), pages 351-365, November.

    Cited by:

    1. Ross A. Williams, 1984. "Interactions Between Government and Private Outlays: Education in Australia, 1949‐50 to 1981‐82," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 60(4), pages 317-325, December.
    2. Feltenstein, Andrew & Morris, Stephen, 1988. "Fiscal stabilization and exchange rate instability," Policy Research Working Paper Series 74, The World Bank.
    3. Jones, Philip & Dawson, Peter, 2007. "`Choice' in collective decision-making processes: Instrumental or expressive approval?," Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics (formerly The Journal of Socio-Economics), Elsevier, vol. 36(1), pages 102-117, February.
    4. Unal Zenginobuz & Antonio Villanacci, 2009. "Subscription Equilibrium with Production: Neutrality and Constrained Suboptimality of Equilibria," Working Papers 2009/03, Bogazici University, Department of Economics.
    5. Villanacci, Antonio & Zenginobuz, Ünal, 2012. "Subscription equilibrium with production: Non-neutrality and constrained suboptimality," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 147(2), pages 407-425.
    6. Rosella Levaggi, 1999. "Does Government Expenditure Crowd Out Private Consumption in Italy? Evidence from a Microeconomic Model," International Review of Applied Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 13(2), pages 241-251.
    7. Eloranta, Jari, 2004. "WARFARE AND WELFARE? Understanding 19th and 20th Century Central Government Spending," The Warwick Economics Research Paper Series (TWERPS) 699, University of Warwick, Department of Economics.
    8. Eloranta, Jari, 2004. "WARFARE AND WELFARE? Understanding 19th and 20th Century Central Government Spending," Economic Research Papers 269593, University of Warwick - Department of Economics.

  15. McLean, Ian W. & Pincus, Jonathan J., 1983. "Did Australian Living Standards Stagnate between 1890 and 1940?," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 43(1), pages 193-202, March.

    Cited by:

    1. Geoffrey Brooke & Lydia Cheung, 2019. "Body Sizes in Nineteenth Century New Zealand: An Empirical Investigation using the NZ Contingents in the Second Boer war," Working Papers 2019-05, Auckland University of Technology, Department of Economics.
    2. Graeme Donald Snooks, 2006. "Dynamics Downunder: Australian Economic Strategy and Performance from the Palaeolithic to the Twenty-first Century," CEPR Discussion Papers 539, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Economics, Australian National University.
    3. Rajabrata Banerjee & John K. Wilson, 2016. "Roles of Education in Productivity Growth in Australia, 1860–1939," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 92(296), pages 47-66, March.
    4. Ian McLean, 2004. "Australian Economic Growth in Historical Perspective," Method and Hist of Econ Thought 0410003, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    5. Andrew Seltzer & Martin Shanahan & Claire Wright, 2022. "The Rise and Fall and Rise (?) of Economic History in Australia," CEH Discussion Papers 05, Centre for Economic History, Research School of Economics, Australian National University.
    6. Graeme Snooks, 2008. "Australia’s Longrun Economic Strategy, Performance, and Policy: A New Dynamic Perspective," GDSC Working Papers 002, Institute of Global Dynamic Systems.
    7. David Merrett & Simon Ville, 2011. "Tariffs, Subsidies, And Profits: A Re‐Assessment Of Structural Change In Australia 1901–39," Australian Economic History Review, Economic History Society of Australia and New Zealand, vol. 51(1), pages 46-70, March.
    8. Johan Fourie & Martine Mariotti & Kris Inwood, 2018. "Military technology and sample selection bias," Working Papers 03/2018, Stellenbosch University, Department of Economics.

  16. Kleiman, Ephraim & Pincus, Jonathan J, 1982. "The Australian Export Expansion Grants Scheme," Australian Economic Papers, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 21(38), pages 85-105, June.

    Cited by:

    1. Ephraim Kleiman & Jonathan J. Pincus, 1981. "The Cyclical Effects of Incremental Export Subsidies," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 57(2), pages 140-149, June.
    2. E. Kleiman & J.J. Pincus, 1986. "Incremental Export Subsidies: A Rejoinder," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 62(1), pages 93-94, March.
    3. Aharonson, Vered & Andelman, David & Zilman, Anton & Pincus, Philip A. & Raphaël, Elie, 1994. "Polymer adsorption at liquid/air interfaces under lateral pressure," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 204(1), pages 1-16.

  17. Ephraim Kleiman & Jonathan J. Pincus, 1981. "The Cyclical Effects of Incremental Export Subsidies," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 57(2), pages 140-149, June.

    Cited by:

    1. E. Kleiman & J.J. Pincus, 1986. "Incremental Export Subsidies: A Rejoinder," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 62(1), pages 93-94, March.
    2. Martin Richardson & Simon Wilkie, 1986. "Incremental Export Subsidies," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 62(1), pages 88-92, March.

  18. Pincus, J J, 1975. "Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 83(4), pages 757-778, August.

    Cited by:

    1. Donald Feaver & Kenneth Wilson, 1998. "Unlocking Australia's Contingent Protection Black Box," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 74(224), pages 62-73, March.
    2. Bin, Sheng, 2000. "The Political Economy of Trade Policy in China," Working Papers 10/2000, Copenhagen Business School, Department of Management, Politics & Philosophy.
    3. Michael P. Leidy, 1994. "Trade Policy And Indirect Rent Seeking: A Synthesis Of Recent Work†," Economics and Politics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 6(2), pages 97-118, July.
    4. Rongili Biswas, 2009. "Fiscal Federalism, State Lobbying and Discretionary Finance in India," Working Papers id:1842, eSocialSciences.
    5. Grossman, Gene M. & Helpman, Elhanan, 1995. "Rent Dissipation, Free Riding, and Trade Policy," Foerder Institute for Economic Research Working Papers 275607, Tel-Aviv University > Foerder Institute for Economic Research.
    6. Castellanos, Sergio & Santibañez-Aguilar, José E. & Shapiro, Benjamin B. & Powell, Douglas M. & Peters, Ian M. & Buonassisi, Tonio & Kammen, Daniel M. & Flores-Tlacuahuac, Antonio, 2018. "Sustainable silicon photovoltaics manufacturing in a global market: A techno-economic, tariff and transportation framework," Applied Energy, Elsevier, vol. 212(C), pages 704-719.
    7. Richard Pomfret, 2003. "Trade and Exchange Rate Policies in Formerly Centrally Planned Economies," The World Economy, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 26(4), pages 585-612, April.
    8. Charles P. Kindleberger, 1983. "International Trade and National Prosperity," Cato Journal, Cato Journal, Cato Institute, vol. 3(3), pages 623-644, Winter.
    9. Cahan, Steven F., 1996. "Political use of income: Some experimental evidence from Capitol Hill," Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics (formerly The Journal of Socio-Economics), Elsevier, vol. 25(1), pages 69-87.
    10. Knežević, M. & Milošević, S., 1981. "Exact solution of the impure one-dimensional n-vector model with bilinear and biquadratic exchange interactions," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 107(2), pages 255-279.
    11. Andrew Smith & Graham Brownlow, 2023. "Informal Institutions as Inhibitors of Rent-Seeking Entrepreneurship: Evidence From U.S. Legal History," Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, , vol. 47(6), pages 2323-2346, November.
    12. Jonathan Pincus, 2014. "Public Choice Theory had Negligible Effect on Australian Microeconomic Policy, 1970s to 2000s," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2014-02, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.
    13. John Conybeare, 1984. "Politicians and protection: Tariffs and elections in Australia," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 43(2), pages 203-209, January.
    14. Alexandr Knobel, 2010. "Factors of important Tariff Information," Research Paper Series, Gaidar Institute for Economic Policy, issue 143P.
    15. Xiaokai Yang & Dingsheng Zhang, 1999. "Endogenous Structure of the Division of Labor, Endogenous Trade Policy Regime, and a Dual Structure in Economic Development," CEMA Working Papers 11, China Economics and Management Academy, Central University of Finance and Economics, revised Apr 2000.
    16. Edward Ray, 1989. "The impact of rent seeking activity on U.S. preferential trade and World debt," Review of World Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv), Springer;Institut für Weltwirtschaft (Kiel Institute for the World Economy), vol. 125(3), pages 619-638, September.
    17. John Tressler, 1978. "Political Goods and Trade Theory," The American Economist, Sage Publications, vol. 22(1), pages 51-59, March.
    18. Joseph S Shapiro, 2021. "The Environmental Bias of Trade Policy," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 136(2), pages 831-886.
    19. Wen Mao & Peter Zaleski, 2001. "The Effect of Industry Concentration on Free Riding," Review of Industrial Organization, Springer;The Industrial Organization Society, vol. 19(3), pages 295-303, November.
    20. Knobel, A., 2011. "Inter-industry Import Tariff Differences in Russia," Journal of the New Economic Association, New Economic Association, issue 11, pages 64-84.
    21. Ponzetto, Giacomo & Petrova, Maria & Enikolopov, Ruben, 2011. "The Dracula Effect: Voter Information and Trade Policy," CEPR Discussion Papers 8726, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    22. Glismann, Hans H. & Spinanger, Dean, 1984. "Clothing the world efficiently: The MFA and consumers," Kiel Working Papers 208, Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW Kiel).
    23. Kym Anderson, 1978. "On Why Rates Of Assistance Differ Between Australia'S Rural Industries," Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, vol. 22(2-3), pages 99-114, 08-12.
    24. Irwin, Douglas A, 1994. "The Political Economy of Free Trade: Voting in the British General Election of 1906," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 37(1), pages 75-108, April.
    25. Gael Lagadec, 2014. "Are political support-driven policies always bad? The case of large interest groups," European Journal of Government and Economics, Europa Grande, vol. 3(2), pages 138-147, December.
    26. Emile van Ommeren & Arlo Poletti & Dirk De Bièvre, 2021. "The European Union and the political economy of enforcing international trade rules," European Union Politics, , vol. 22(3), pages 377-400, September.
    27. Dani Rodrik, 1994. "What Does the Political Economy Literature on Trade Policy (Not) Tell UsThat We Ought To Know?," NBER Working Papers 4870, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    28. Giacomo Ponzetto, 2008. "Asymmetric information and trade policy," Economics Working Papers 1253, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, revised Oct 2010.
    29. Mirabelle Muûls & Dimitra Petropoulou, 2013. "A swing state theory of trade protection in the Electoral College," Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 46(2), pages 705-724, May.
    30. Kudo, Tomoshige & Matsubara, Fumitaka & Katsura, Shigetoshi, 1978. "Magnetic properties and distribution of thermal averages of spins in the one-dimensional random mixture of Ising spins of S = 1 and12," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 93(1), pages 255-272.
    31. Adina Ardelean & Carolyn L. Evans, 2013. "Electoral systems and protectionism: an industry‐level analysis," Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 46(2), pages 725-764, May.
    32. David Lake, 2009. "Open economy politics: A critical review," The Review of International Organizations, Springer, vol. 4(3), pages 219-244, September.
    33. Don P. Clark & Donald Bruce, 2006. "Who Bears The Burden Of U.S. Nontariff Measures?," Contemporary Economic Policy, Western Economic Association International, vol. 24(2), pages 274-286, April.
    34. Amrita Saha, 2017. "Trade Policy & Lobbying Effectiveness: Theory and Evidence for India," Working Paper Series 0417, Department of Economics, University of Sussex Business School.
    35. Elias Dinopoulos & Mordechai E. Kreinin, 1991. "The US VER on Machine Tools: Causes and Effects," NBER Chapters, in: Empirical Studies of Commercial Policy, pages 113-134, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    36. Stéphane BECUWE & Radhouane HASNI, 2010. "Green protectionism: the case of textile-clothing sector (In French)," Cahiers du GREThA (2007-2019) 2010-10, Groupe de Recherche en Economie Théorique et Appliquée (GREThA).
    37. Amrita Saha & Vikrant Shirodkar & Thomas C. Lawton, 2023. "Bimodal lobbying and trade policy outcomes: Evidence from corporate political activity under uncertainty in India," Journal of International Business Policy, Palgrave Macmillan, vol. 6(1), pages 24-46, March.
    38. Christis G. Tombazos, 2003. "Unprotective Tariffs, Ineffective Liberalization, and Other Mysteries: An Investigation of the Endogenous Dimensions of Trade Policy Formation in Australia," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 70(1), pages 49-74, July.
    39. Kishore Gawande & Alok K. Bohara, 2000. "Errors‐in‐Variables Bounds in a Tobit Model of Endogenous Protection," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 66(4), pages 881-905, April.
    40. Panagariya, Arvind & Rodrik, Dani, 1993. "Political-Economy Arguments for a Uniform Tariff," International Economic Review, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania and Osaka University Institute of Social and Economic Research Association, vol. 34(3), pages 685-703, August.
    41. John Conybeare, 1978. "Public Policy and the Australian Tariff Structure," Australian Journal of Management, Australian School of Business, vol. 3(1), pages 49-63, April.
    42. Friedrich Schneider & Jörg Naumann, 1982. "Interest groups in democracies — How influential are they?," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 38(3), pages 281-303, January.
    43. Wen Li Cheng & Meng‐Chun Liu & Xiaokai Yang, 2000. "A Ricardian Model with Endogenous Comparative Advantage and Endogenous Trade Policy Regimes," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 76(233), pages 172-182, June.
    44. Chen, Baizhu & Feng, Yi, 2001. "Openness and trade policy in China: an industrial analysis," China Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 11(4), pages 323-341.
    45. Thorsten Drautzburg & Igor Livshits & Mark L. J. Wright, 2022. "Polarized Contributions but Convergent Agendas," Working Papers 22-29, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
    46. Chang, Kuo-I & Hayakawa, Kazunobu, 2012. "Selection and utilization of the early harvest list : evidence from the Free Trade Agreement between China and Taiwan," IDE Discussion Papers 365, Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization(JETRO).
    47. Robert Pahre, 1998. "Reactions and Reciprocity," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Peace Science Society (International), vol. 42(4), pages 467-492, August.
    48. Robert C. Feenstra & Jagdish N. Bhagwati, 1982. "Tariff Seeking and the Efficient Tariff," NBER Chapters, in: Import Competition and Response, pages 245-262, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    49. Jeffry A. Frieden & David A. Lake, 2005. "International Relations as a Social Science: Rigor and Relevance," The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, , vol. 600(1), pages 136-156, July.
    50. Charles J Finocchiaro & Jeffery A Jenkins, 2016. "Distributive politics, the electoral connection, and the antebellum US Congress: The case of military service pensions," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 28(2), pages 192-224, April.
    51. Oscar Bajo & Angel Torres, 1991. "Los determinantes de la protección en la industria manufacturera española," Investigaciones Economicas, Fundación SEPI, vol. 15(2), pages 457-480, May.
    52. Afontsev Serguey, 2000. "Political Economy of Tariff Protection in Russia: an Empirical Study," EERC Working Paper Series 99-16e, EERC Research Network, Russia and CIS.
    53. Potters, Jan & Sloof, Randolph, 1996. "Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 12(3), pages 403-442, November.
    54. Jae Chung, 1992. "Rivalry for export promotions," Open Economies Review, Springer, vol. 3(1), pages 23-35, February.
    55. Richard Pomfret, 2000. "Regional Trade Arrangements and Economies in Transition: The Central Asian Countries," School of Economics and Public Policy Working Papers 2000-09, University of Adelaide, School of Economics and Public Policy.
    56. Mustapha Nabli, 1990. "The political economy of trade liberalization in developing countries," Open Economies Review, Springer, vol. 1(2), pages 111-145, June.
    57. Peter Murrell, 1984. "An examination of the factors affecting the formation of interest groups in OECD countries," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 43(2), pages 151-171, January.
    58. Lotta Moberg, 2018. "Liberalizing Rent-Seeking: How Export Processing Zones Can Save or Sink an Economy," Journal of Private Enterprise, The Association of Private Enterprise Education, vol. 33(Winter 20), pages 61-89.
    59. Tharakan, P.K.M. & Greenaway, David & Kerstens, Birgit, 2006. "Anti-dumping and excess injury margins in the European Union: A counterfactual analysis," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 22(3), pages 653-674, September.
    60. Josh Ederington & Jenny Minier, 2008. "Reconsidering the empirical evidence on the Grossman‐Helpman model of endogenous protection," Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 41(2), pages 501-516, May.
    61. Richard Damania & Per Fredriksson & Thomas Osang, 2004. "Collusion, Collective Action and Protection: Theory and Evidence," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 121(3), pages 279-308, February.
    62. Galia J. Benítez, 2018. "Business Lobbying: Mapping Policy Networks in Brazil in Mercosur," Social Sciences, MDPI, vol. 7(10), pages 1-30, October.
    63. John Quiggin, 1987. "Egoistic Rationality and Public Choice: A Critical Review of Theory and Evidence," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 63(1), pages 10-21, March.
    64. Malozovsky, Yu.M. & Rozenbaum, V.M., 1991. "Orientational ordering in two-dimensional systems with long-range interaction," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 175(1), pages 127-145.
    65. S. Lael Brainard, 1991. "Protecting Losers: Optimal Diversification, Insurance, and Trade Policy," NBER Working Papers 3773, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    66. Dijck, P. van, 1988. "The objectives and feasibility of a preferential trading system among developing countries," Serie Research Memoranda 0048, VU University Amsterdam, Faculty of Economics, Business Administration and Econometrics.
    67. Magee, Stephen & Lee, Hak Loh & Lee, Hongshik, 2017. "Simple measures of endogenous free-riding in protectionist lobbies," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 60(C), pages 324-333.
    68. Metcalfe, Mark R. & Goodwin, Barry K., 1999. "An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of Trade Policy Protection in the U.S. Manufacturing Sector," Journal of Policy Modeling, Elsevier, vol. 21(2), pages 153-165, March.
    69. Bibo Liang, 2007. "Political Economy of US Trade Policy towards China," China & World Economy, Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, vol. 15(5), pages 50-64, September.
    70. Carter, Richard, 1983. "Séparation, annexion, et fédéralisme : au-delà des préceptes normatifs usuels," L'Actualité Economique, Société Canadienne de Science Economique, vol. 59(3), pages 596-619, septembre.
    71. Czyżewski, Bazyli, 2016. "Political Rents of European Farmers in the Sustainable Development Paradigm. International, national and regional perspective," MPRA Paper 74253, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    72. kishore gawande & pravin krishna, 2005. "The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Empirical Approaches," International Trade 0503003, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    73. Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto, 2011. "Heterogeneous Information and Trade Policy," 2011 Meeting Papers 189, Society for Economic Dynamics.
    74. Eli Noam, 1985. "A local regulator's rewards for conformity in policy," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 45(3), pages 291-302, January.

  19. Pincus, Jonathan James, 1974. "A Positive Theory of Tariff Formation Applied to Nineteenth Century United States," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 34(1), pages 273-274, March.

    Cited by:

    1. Patrick A. Messerlin, 1982. "Les déterminants de la demande de protection : le cas français," Revue Économique, Programme National Persée, vol. 33(6), pages 1001-1023.
    2. Lawson, J.O., 1977. "Transport properties determinations of the one-dimensional, half-filled band Holstein-Frölich modified Hubbard model," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 89(1), pages 139-148.

Chapters

  1. J. J. Pincus, 1986. "Why Have US Tariffs Fallen Since 1930?," Palgrave Macmillan Books, in: R. H. Snape (ed.), Issues in World Trade Policy, chapter 12, pages 238-256, Palgrave Macmillan.

    Cited by:

    1. Dani Rodrik, 1994. "What Does the Political Economy Literature on Trade Policy (Not) Tell UsThat We Ought To Know?," NBER Working Papers 4870, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.