IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ekd/004912/5300.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Structural change in agriculture – an equilibrium approach

Author

Listed:
  • Stefan Kersting
  • JProf. Silke Huettel
  • Prof. Martin Odening

Abstract

Structural change is a fundamental phenomenon that accompanies the development of market-based economies. Structural change in agriculture can be understood in a broad sense as adjustments of economic entities in the agricultural sector in response to various driving forces. Depending on the perspective and the aggregation level of the analysis these entities are single farms, value chains, markets, or institutions. Decisions that affect structural change are, for example, market entries and exits of farms, growth and shrinkage, change of the production structure or the adoption of new technologies (Chavas, 2001). These decisions not only have an impact on business goals, such as profitability and competitiveness, but also on public goals, such as employment, sustainability, and food security. Understanding causal relationships between entrepreneurial decisions, political instruments, and exogenous factors is an indispensable requirement for assessing and predicting structural change as well as for governing structural change in terms of economic, environmental, and social objectives. Due to the complexity of the involved causal relationships modelling structural change is usually carried out on a very abstract level using restrictive assumptions. This paper suggests an equilibrium modelling framework that supports the analysis of structural change in an economy considering three important characteristics: First, entry and exist decisions of farms as well as prices and production output are determined endogenously. Second, decisions are made in a dynamic framework. This allows to track changes in the composition of the sector. Third, the model is driven by a stochastic component. Thus our model resembles a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model (DSGE). To our best knowledge, this is the first time that this model class has been applied in an agricultural context. The DSGE modelling framework is used explore a long-lasting puzzle in agricultural economics: What is the impact of production quota on the dynamics of structural change? It is frequently hypothesized that the introduction of a production quota slows down structural change and hinders efficient adjustment processes (Colman, 2000). But is this also true if quotas are traded (Barichello, 1995)? Clearly, a sectoral production quota causes a strong interdependence of farms within this sector. Farms can only grow if free capacities are available and thus exits of other farms are crucial for any further industry development. From a more general perspective, this kind of interdependency can be generated by the existence of any production factor which is limited on a sectoral level, as for example agricultural land. Production capacity is thus a valuable asset and determines a farm’s liquidation value. As a consequence, the price for investing in additional capacity depends also on the exit and shrinking rate of the other firms determining free capacity (e.g. Weiss, 1999 or Zepeda, 1995). If firms benefit from economies of size investing in production capacity is an option to increase profitability and competitiveness. However, under capacity constraints like production quotas this is more expensive (e.g. Richards and Jeffrey 1997). Against this background we conjecture that profit maximizing firms do not base their investment/disinvestment decision on an isolated view, it is rather that regional structure and its expected evolution is taken into consideration. The literature offers different theoretic approaches to investigate the impact of capacity constraints on entry/exit of firms in an industry. However, considering the interaction among the firms and the consequence on structural development are not well elaborated. Generally, game theoretic models are capable to model growth and shrinkage of firms in a given market with endogenous supply, but they are difficult to handle, in particular if there are more than two firms within the market (e.g. Besanko and Doraszelski, 2004). The real options approach primarily focusses on the optimal timing of investment and neglects the mentioned interdependency of farms’ decisions and the relation between exit and investment (cf. among others Dixit and Pindyck, 1994, or Leahy, 1993). Authors like Jovanovic (1982) and Hopenhayn (1992) model entry and exit of firms into an industry endogenously, however, without modelling of capacity constraints. In view of the relevance of capacity constraints in general and particularly for the agricultural sector, it is somehow surprising that the literature has little to offer with regard to a formalized theoretical analysis of the impact of capacity constraints like production quotas or land constraints on structural change. Against this background, our objective is to investigate how farms’ exit decisions are affected by the uncertain ability to invest in production capacity, and vice versa. We aim to show the implications for the structural change of the agricultural industry when firms take prospective entry/exit of other firms into consideration for their own optimal investment/disinvestment behaviour. Our analysis will improve the understanding of the interdependency between entry and exit of farms and shed light on the question whether the inability to expand production capacity increases the likelihood that inefficient firms leave the market. For this reason, we incorporate capacity constraints into the model as proposed by Hopenhayn (1992) and derive a dynamic stochastic equilibrium for a finite time horizon. We further apply this model to different market structures – structure is here defined as firm size distribution – and show how the industry dynamics depend on the underlying distribution of firms and are affected by the capacity constraint. We employ the stochastic dynamic framework proposed by Hopenhayn (1992), to analyse entry and exit in an industry over a finite time horizon. A continuum of firms is considered, to model a perfectly competitive output market. The firms are assumed to be identical and to produce a homogeneous good. They differ just with respect to their firm specific productivity shock which is stochastic and follows a Markov process. The structure of the industry at a given point in time is described by the distribution of productivity shocks among all firms. In each period, all active firms choose their optimal amount of output according to their own productivity and a given market price. Production incurs a fixed cost which is the same for all firms and total market demand is described by an inverse demand function. At the end of each period all incumbents decide whether to leave or stay in the industry. If they cease production they receive a positive premium depending on the total mass of the industry. This takes into account, that the firm’s production capacity as a liquidation value is more valuable when there are more firms in the industry looking for additional production capacity. Continuing firms are hit with a new productivity shock and start production in the next period. A firm stays in the industry if its expected discounted future profits offset the exit premium. The expected profits depend on a firm’s current productivity as well as on the future price sequence. The exit-point describes the critical threshold for being indifferent between staying in or leaving the market. All firms with a productivity above the exit-point stay in the industry while all firms with a lower productivity take the exit premium and quit. New firms can enter the industry in each period, but they have to pay entry costs which are affected by the mass of the industry. If there are more firms willing to enter the market, the entry is more expensive. Each new firm gets a productivity shock drawn from the same distribution function and there will be firms entering the industry as long as their expected future profits cover the entry costs. In this regard, the term “new firms” also refers to active firms who invest the entry costs and expect to improve their productivity this way. The mass of new entering firms together with the exit-point and the stochastic process for productivity shocks fully describe the change of industry structure from one period to the next. We make some explicit assumptions on the stochastic process and other functions to show that a dynamic stochastic equilibrium exists. In such an equilibrium the firms base their exit/entry decision on the evolution of output prices, exit premium and entry costs in future periods. We compute equilibria for different scenarios to show the influence of capacity constraints on industry dynamics. Furthermore, we check how changes of the underlying starting distribution of firm productivity affect the equilibrium outcome and which implications this has for the structural change of highly or weakly concentrated regions in the agricultural sector. We find that both, the underlying starting distribution and the imposed capacity constraints, have an impact on firms’ investment and disinvestment decision in a dynamic equilibrium. In a scenario without capacity constraints we observe almost all new firms enter the industry in the first period. If we incorporate capacity constraints, however, entry occurs also in higher time periods. This is due to the varying entry costs which would be too high if all firms entered the industry at the same time. Thus, some firms wait for others to leave the market first and postpone their investment to a later date. In addition to this, we find that less productive firms tend to stay longer in the industry if the entry of new firms is restricted by capacity constraints. Another interesting finding is that the equilibrium outcome and the structure of the industry in subsequent periods are sensitive to the assumed starting distribution. This could be an instrument to make explicit statements about the prospective structure of the agricultural sector. By fitting the starting distribution to the firm size concentration in a selected region and calibrating crucial parameters of the model, we could be able to simulate changes of this industry structure for a number of time periods.

Suggested Citation

  • Stefan Kersting & JProf. Silke Huettel & Prof. Martin Odening, 2013. "Structural change in agriculture – an equilibrium approach," EcoMod2013 5300, EcoMod.
  • Handle: RePEc:ekd:004912:5300
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://ecomod.net/system/files/EcoMod2013_Kersting_Structural_change_in_agriculture_an_equilibrium_approach_0.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. David Besanko & Ulrich Doraszelski, 2004. "Capacity Dynamics and Endogenous Asymmetries in Firm Size," RAND Journal of Economics, The RAND Corporation, vol. 35(1), pages 23-49, Spring.
    2. Doraszelski, Ulrich & Pakes, Ariel, 2007. "A Framework for Applied Dynamic Analysis in IO," Handbook of Industrial Organization, in: Mark Armstrong & Robert Porter (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, edition 1, volume 3, chapter 30, pages 1887-1966, Elsevier.
    3. Judd, Kenneth L., 1985. "The law of large numbers with a continuum of IID random variables," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 35(1), pages 19-25, February.
    4. Christoph R. Weiss, 1999. "Farm Growth and Survival: Econometric Evidence for Individual Farms in Upper Austria," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, vol. 81(1), pages 103-116.
    5. Péter Eső & Volker Nocke & Lucy White, 2010. "Competition for scarce resources," RAND Journal of Economics, RAND Corporation, vol. 41(3), pages 524-548, September.
    6. Timothy Dunne & Shawn D. Klimek & Mark J. Roberts & Daniel Yi Xu, 2013. "Entry, exit, and the determinants of market structure," RAND Journal of Economics, RAND Corporation, vol. 44(3), pages 462-487, September.
    7. Pauli Murto, 2004. "Exit in Duopoly Under Uncertainty," RAND Journal of Economics, The RAND Corporation, vol. 35(1), pages 111-127, Spring.
    8. Chad Syverson, 2004. "Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 112(6), pages 1181-1222, December.
    9. Richard Ericson & Ariel Pakes, 1995. "Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for Empirical Work," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 62(1), pages 53-82.
    10. Ayal Kimhi & Ray Bollman, 1999. "Family farm dynamics in Canada and Israel: the case of farm exits," Agricultural Economics, International Association of Agricultural Economists, vol. 21(1), pages 69-79, August.
    11. Dixit, Avinash K, 1989. "Entry and Exit Decisions under Uncertainty," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 97(3), pages 620-638, June.
    12. Jovanovic, Boyan, 1982. "Selection and the Evolution of Industry," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 50(3), pages 649-670, May.
    13. Richard Ericson & Ariel Pakes, 1992. "An Alternative Theory of Firm and Industry Dynamics," Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers 1041, Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University.
    14. Ky–sti Pietola & Minna V”re & Alfons Oude Lansink, 2003. "Timing and type of exit from farming: farmers' early retirement programmes in Finland," European Review of Agricultural Economics, Oxford University Press and the European Agricultural and Applied Economics Publications Foundation, vol. 30(1), pages 99-116, March.
    15. Timothy J. Richards, 1995. "Supply Management and Productivity Growth in Alberta Dairy," Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie, Canadian Agricultural Economics Society/Societe canadienne d'agroeconomie, vol. 43(3), pages 421-434, November.
    16. Chavas, Jean-Paul, 2001. "Structural change in agricultural production: Economics, technology and policy," Handbook of Agricultural Economics, in: B. L. Gardner & G. C. Rausser (ed.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, edition 1, volume 1, chapter 5, pages 263-285, Elsevier.
    17. Oskam, A. J. & Speijers, D. P., 1992. "Quota mobility and quota values : Influence on the structural development of dairy farming," Food Policy, Elsevier, vol. 17(1), pages 41-52, February.
    18. Barichello, Richard R., 1995. "Overview Of Canadian Agricultural Policy Systems," Proceedings of the 1st Agricultural and Food Policy Systems Information Workshop, 1995: Understanding Canada\United States Grain Disputes 16747, Farm Foundation, Agricultural and Food Policy Systems Information Workshops.
    19. Timothy J. Richards & Scott R. Jeffrey, 1997. "The Effect of Supply Management on Herd Size in Alberta Dairy," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, vol. 79(2), pages 555-565.
    20. Marc J. Melitz, 2003. "The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 71(6), pages 1695-1725, November.
    21. David Colman & Michael Burton & Dan Rigby & Jeremy Franks, 2002. "Structural Change and Policy Reform in the UK Dairy Sector," Journal of Agricultural Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 53(3), pages 645-663, November.
    22. Hanazono, Makoto & Yang, Huanxing, 2009. "Dynamic entry and exit with uncertain cost positions," International Journal of Industrial Organization, Elsevier, vol. 27(3), pages 474-487, May.
    23. Fariñas, Jose C. & Ruano, Sonia, 2005. "Firm productivity, heterogeneity, sunk costs and market selection," International Journal of Industrial Organization, Elsevier, vol. 23(7-8), pages 505-534, September.
    24. Colman, David, 2000. "Inefficiencies in the UK milk quota system," Food Policy, Elsevier, vol. 25(1), pages 1-16, February.
    25. Robert Novy-Marx, 2007. "An Equilibrium Model of Investment Under Uncertainty," The Review of Financial Studies, Society for Financial Studies, vol. 20(5), pages 1461-1502, 2007 29.
    26. Hopenhayn, Hugo A, 1992. "Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 60(5), pages 1127-1150, September.
    27. Lydia Zepeda, 1995. "Asymmetry and Nonstationarity in the Farm Size Distribution of Wisconsin Milk Producers: An Aggregate Analysis," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, vol. 77(4), pages 837-852.
    28. Feldman, Mark & Gilles, Christian, 1985. "An expository note on individual risk without aggregate uncertainty," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 35(1), pages 26-32, February.
    29. John V. Leahy, 1993. "Investment in Competitive Equilibrium: The Optimality of Myopic Behavior," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 108(4), pages 1105-1133.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Odening, Martin & Ritter, Matthias & Hüttel, Silke, 2015. "The term structure of land lease rates," 2015 AAEA & WAEA Joint Annual Meeting, July 26-28, San Francisco, California 201664, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Kersting, Stefan & Hüttel, Silke & Odening, Martin, 2015. "Structural change in agriculture under capacity constraints: An equilibrium approach," Thuenen-Series of Applied Economic Theory 140, University of Rostock, Institute of Economics.
    2. Kersting, Stefan & Hüttel, Silke & Odening, Martin, 2016. "Industry dynamics under production constraints — The case of the EU dairy sector," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 55(C), pages 135-151.
    3. Jianjun Miao, 2005. "Optimal Capital Structure and Industry Dynamics," Journal of Finance, American Finance Association, vol. 60(6), pages 2621-2659, December.
    4. Feil, Jan-Henning & Musshoff, Oliver, 2013. "Investment, disinvestment and policy impact analysis in the dairy sector: a real options approach," Structural Change in Agriculture/Strukturwandel im Agrarsektor (SiAg) Working Papers 159229, Humboldt University Berlin, Department of Agricultural Economics.
    5. Joachim Wagner, 2016. "Exports, Imports and Firm Survival: First Evidence for Manufacturing Enterprises in Germany," World Scientific Book Chapters, in: Microeconometrics of International Trade, chapter 10, pages 341-367, World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd..
    6. Andrew B. Bernard & Stephen J. Redding & Peter K. Schott, 2009. "Products and Productivity," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 111(4), pages 681-709, December.
    7. Eslava, Marcela & Haltiwanger, John & Kugler, Adriana & Kugler, Maurice, 2004. "The effects of structural reforms on productivity and profitability enhancing reallocation: evidence from Colombia," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 75(2), pages 333-371, December.
    8. Laura Alfaro & Anusha Chari, 2014. "Deregulation, Misallocation, and Size: Evidence from India," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 57(4), pages 897-936.
    9. Lucia Foster & John Haltiwanger & Chad Syverson, 2008. "Reallocation, Firm Turnover, and Efficiency: Selection on Productivity or Profitability?," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 98(1), pages 394-425, March.
    10. Joachim Wagner, 2015. "25 Jahre Nutzung vertraulicher Firmenpaneldaten der amtlichen Statistik für wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Forschung: Produkte, Projekte, Probleme, Perspektiven," AStA Wirtschafts- und Sozialstatistisches Archiv, Springer;Deutsche Statistische Gesellschaft - German Statistical Society, vol. 9(2), pages 83-106, November.
    11. Florin Maican & Matilda Orth, 2017. "Productivity Dynamics and the Role of ‘Big-Box’ Entrants in Retailing," Journal of Industrial Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 65(2), pages 397-438, June.
    12. Blanchard, Pierre, 2012. "The determinants of firm exit in the French food industries," Revue d'Etudes en Agriculture et Environnement, Editions NecPlus, vol. 93(02), pages 193-212, June.
    13. Eslava, Marcela & Haltiwanger, John C. & Kugler, Adriana & Kugler, Maurice, 2009. "Trade Reforms and Market Selection: Evidence from Manufacturing Plants in Colombia," IZA Discussion Papers 4256, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).
    14. Poschke, Markus, 2009. "Employment protection, firm selection, and growth," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 56(8), pages 1074-1085, November.
    15. Rene Söllner, 2010. "Product Diversification and Labor Productivity Dispersion in German Manufacturing Industries," Jena Economics Research Papers 2010-028, Friedrich-Schiller-University Jena.
    16. Daron Acemoglu & Martin Kaae Jensen, 2015. "Robust Comparative Statics in Large Dynamic Economies," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 123(3), pages 587-640.
    17. Raphael Bergoeing Vela & Andrés Hernando & Andrea Repetto, 2010. "Market Reforms and Efficiency Gains in Chile," Estudios de Economia, University of Chile, Department of Economics, vol. 37(2 Year 20), pages 217-242, December.
    18. Richard I. Harris & Qian Cher Li, 2011. "The Determinants of Firm Exit from Exporting: Evidence for the UK," International Journal of the Economics of Business, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 18(3), pages 381-397, November.
    19. Flora Bellone & Patrick Musso & Michel Quéré & Lionel Nesta, 2006. "Productivity and Market Selection of French Manufacturing Firms in the Nineties," Revue de l'OFCE, Presses de Sciences-Po, vol. 97(5), pages 319-349.
    20. Henk L. M. Kox, 2013. "Export Decisions of Services Firms Between Agglomeration Effects and Market-Entry Costs," Advances in Spatial Science, in: Juan R. Cuadrado-Roura (ed.), Service Industries and Regions, edition 127, chapter 0, pages 177-201, Springer.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Germany; General equilibrium modeling (CGE); Agricultural issues;
    All these keywords.

    NEP fields

    This paper has been announced in the following NEP Reports:

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ekd:004912:5300. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Theresa Leary (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ecomoea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.