IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/eab/microe/22405.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

LARGE FARMERS IN THE LEASE MARKET - How and Why Do They Enter the Market? Are Marginal Farmers Affected in the Process?

Author

Listed:
  • C. S. Murty

    (Centre for Economic and Social Studies)

Abstract

1. The importance of economically dominant farmers is increasing in the lease market for agricultural land. This is particularly evident from the NSS data of 1981-82 and 1991-92 on the percentage of operational holdings and operated area under tenancy and on the shares of large farmers in total tenanted holdings and tenanted area. Increase in the significance of large farmers in the lease market is a disquieting development because : m Taking advantage of tenancy laws the farmers can get conferred ownership or occupancy rights on tenanted lands under their control. m They can take advantage of the laws and cause hardship to petty lessors (landlords) and, in particular, to institutional lessors. m They can displace petty peasants from the lease market. m They can expose poor tenants to a process of self-exploitation by vying with them for land in the lease market. 2. The once isolated incidents of the practice of large farmers taking land on lease by now (1991-92) spread to new regions and got intensified in certain others. Thus in the states of AP, Assam, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerala, Punjab, Rajasthan, and to a lesser extent in MP, UP and TN large farmers have become a force to reckon with in the lease market. 3. The modus operandi of large farmers seeking to edge-out their competitors in the lease market is that they offer rent in fixed cash, invariably at the beginning of the season, to their lessors in return for the lease of land. The farmers appeal to the compulsions of the lessors for secure rental receipts by offering to pay fixed cash rents. Petty peasants, being less able to do so, lose out to these farmers in competition for tenanted land. 3 4. The increasing dominance of large tenants does not, however, appear to be at the expense of the poorest of the poor marginal tenants. Although marginal tenants got dislodged in some states consequent upon an increase in the importance of large tenants between 1981-82 and 1991- 92, there are also states where both classes of tenants secured greater hold on the lease market. The proportions of holdings and area under tenancy with large farmers and those with marginal farmers bear no relationship whatever in the 1991-92 cross-section data of major states. But it should not come as a great relief, for it is possible that marginal tenants are now obliged to pay higher rents than earlier in trying to stay in competition with large tenants. 5. The notion that the costliness of new technology compels poor peasants to voluntarily opt out of the lease market and the resultant increase in the supply of land for lease enables large farmers to gain ascendancy in the lease market has little support in the data of recent times. There is only one state, Haryana, where the increase in the real cost of cultivation between 1981-82 and 1991-92 culminated in a decrease in the hold of marginal farmers and a simultaneous increase in the importance of large farmers in the lease market. The cost factor is also found unimportant in influencing the leasing behaviour of marginal farmers even when the crosssection data of Indian states pertaining to 1991-92 is examined. The peasants do not appear to be opting out, rather, they are being driven out. 6. High wage rates seem to favour mechanization of farming operations and with it the operation of large holdings. Farmers who are constrained to increase their ownership holdings because of ceiling laws are, therefore, making their way into the lease market for agricultural land. 7. The entry of large farmers into the lease market may further capitalist development in the agricultural sector. But in the process numerous prospective tenants from the poorer sections can get distanced from the lease market. The institution of land tenancy which derives its legitimacy on the ground that it would help poor peasants to gain access to tenanted land and thereby would fulfill their hope of advancing on the agrarian ladder 4 will be of no avail. It can also give rise to a situation where, petty tenants, in trying to compete with large tenants for tenanted land will end up paying rents higher than the usual to their landlords. Besides, sooner or later, the process can have a dampening effect on real wages of agricultural labour and can stunt the growth of rural employment. 8. Therefore, it seems important to make tenancy laws sufficiently stringent to restrict the entry into the lease market only to petty peasants. The quantitative significance of the incidence of tenancy among large farmers is high enough, though in a relative context, to enact and enforce such exacting laws. The surplus land distributed in the country up to September, 1991 was 19.48 lakh hectares while the tenanted land under the control of large farmers (with operated land in excess of 10 hectares) as of 1991- 92 was 21.63 lakh hectares. Apart from the land leased-in by this class of farmers there is also the land which was leased-in by other relatively higher classes of farmers. And what is more, even the NSS estimates of land under lease, though are on a far higher side compared to the leased-in land as per Agricultural Census, are admittedly underestimates themselves. By preventing large farmers from entering into the lease market, it should be possible to bring down inequity in the distribution of operated land, an objective which is sought to be achieved by allowing tenancy. Such a step is also desirable in the interest of wages and employment in the agricultural sector. Also, as a means to increase the access of land to the rural poor, the policy of barring large farmers from the lease market assumes importance, in view of the closing-in of the possibilities to acquire and distribute land accruing on account of ceiling laws. 9. In sum, it is necessary to rid the large tenant of the lease market in the interest of the poor peasant, who yearns to lease-in a piece of land. The notion that the petty peasant is opting out of the lease market because of costliness of new technology seems unfounded. The peasant is not opting out, rather the large farmer is forcing him to withdraw from the market by appealing to the need of his lessor for secure rental receipts and by paying him rent in fixed cash. It is in the interest of the large farmer to drive out the petty cultivator from the lease market and thereby gain control over it, be5 cause mechanization of farming operations, in the context of high wages, is making heavy demands on him to expand the size of his operational holding. With the scope to enlarge the ownership holding having decreased, more because of the deterrent effect of the land ceiling laws, the large farmer has no option but to lease-in land to expand the size of holding to put his capital assets to optimum use. Large farmers may contribute to capitalist development in agriculture. But development of capitalist relations may lead to proletarianisation of large sections of the rural working classes.

Suggested Citation

  • C. S. Murty, 2004. "LARGE FARMERS IN THE LEASE MARKET - How and Why Do They Enter the Market? Are Marginal Farmers Affected in the Process?," Microeconomics Working Papers 22405, East Asian Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Handle: RePEc:eab:microe:22405
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://www.eaber.org/node/22405
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Bliss, C. J. & Stern, N. H., 1982. "Palanpur: The Economy of an Indian Village," OUP Catalogue, Oxford University Press, number 9780198284192.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Mohammed SHARIF, 2000. "Inverted “S”—The complete neoclassical labour-supply function," International Labour Review, International Labour Organization, vol. 139(4), pages 409-435, December.
    2. Michael Hubbard, 1997. "The ‘New Institutional Economics’ In Agricultural Development: Insights And Challenges," Journal of Agricultural Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 48(1‐3), pages 239-249, January.
    3. Pierre Dubois & Bruno Jullien & Thierry Magnac, 2008. "Formal and Informal Risk Sharing in LDCs: Theory and Empirical Evidence," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 76(4), pages 679-725, July.
    4. Ayala-Cantu, Luciano & Morando, Bruno, 2020. "Rental markets, gender, and land certificates: Evidence from Vietnam," Food Policy, Elsevier, vol. 94(C).
    5. Bezabih, Mintewab & Holden, Stein, 2010. "The Role of Land Certification in Reducing Gender Gaps in Productivity in Rural Ethiopia," RFF Working Paper Series dp-10-23-efd, Resources for the Future.
    6. John Lodewijks, 1994. "Anthropologists and economists: conflict or cooperation?," Journal of Economic Methodology, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 1(1), pages 81-104.
    7. Mariapia MENDOLA, 2005. "Farm households production theories: a review of institutional and behavioural responses," Departmental Working Papers 2005-01, Department of Economics, Management and Quantitative Methods at Università degli Studi di Milano.
    8. Sarmistha Pal & Jocelyn Kynch, 2000. "Determinants of occupational change and mobility in rural India," Applied Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 32(12), pages 1559-1573.
    9. Kijima, Yoko & Tabetando, Rayner, 2020. "Efficiency and equity of rural land markets and the impact on income: Evidence in Kenya and Uganda from 2003 to 2015," Land Use Policy, Elsevier, vol. 91(C).
    10. Chris Elbers & Peter Lanjouw, 2019. "The distributional impact of structural transformation in rural India: Model-based simulation and case-study evidence," WIDER Working Paper Series wp-2019-33, World Institute for Development Economic Research (UNU-WIDER).
    11. Bharat Ramaswami & Shamika Ravi & S.D. Chopra, 2003. "Risk management in agriculture," Discussion Papers 03-08, Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi.
    12. Hagos, Hosaena Gebru & Holden, Stein T., 2013. "Reverse-share-tenancy and Marshallian Inefficiency: Landowners’ bargaining power and sharecroppers’ productivity," IFPRI discussion papers 1270, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
    13. Heyer, Judith, 2020. "How Lives Change," Review of Agrarian Studies, Foundation for Agrarian Studies, vol. 10(1), July.
    14. Jayaraman, Rajshri & Lanjouw, Peter, 1999. "The Evolution of Poverty and Inequality in Indian Villages," The World Bank Research Observer, World Bank, vol. 14(1), pages 1-30, February.
    15. Rambonilaza, Mbolatiana, 2004. "Normes sociales et productivité dans le processus d’appariement des contrats agricoles," L'Actualité Economique, Société Canadienne de Science Economique, vol. 80(4), pages 571-592, Décembre.
    16. Martin Ravallion, 2013. "The Idea of Antipoverty Policy," NBER Working Papers 19210, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    17. Keijiro Otsuka & Yanyan Liu & Futoshi Yamauchi, 2016. "The future of small farms in Asia," Development Policy Review, Overseas Development Institute, vol. 34(3), pages 441-461, May.
    18. Palanisami, Kuppannan, 2009. "Water markets as a demand management option: potentials, problems and prospects," Book Chapters,, International Water Management Institute.
    19. Deininger, Klaus & Ali, Daniel Ayalew & Alemu, Tekie, 2008. "Impacts of land certification on tenure security, investment, and land markets : evidence from Ethiopia," Policy Research Working Paper Series 4764, The World Bank.
    20. Jeffrey A. Flory, 2011. "Micro-Savings & Informal Insurance in Villages: How Financial Deepening Affects Safety Nets of the Poor, A Natural Field Experiment," Working Papers 2011-008, Becker Friedman Institute for Research In Economics.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Farmers; Lease market; Marginal farmers;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • R31 - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics - - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location - - - Housing Supply and Markets

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:eab:microe:22405. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Shiro Armstrong (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/eaberau.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.