IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/pubcho/v54y1987i1p19-25.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

The textile bill of 1985: The determinants of congressional voting patterns

Author

Listed:
  • Suzanne Tosini
  • Edward Tower

Abstract

The following tables show the results of the probit analysis for the Senate and the House. A table including results for different combinations of the independent variables is included in an unpublished appendix available from the authors upon request. The results of the probit analysis for the Senate are shown in Table 1. All the variables except EXP had the expected signs, however the results indicate that the two other employment variables and party affiliation are the only factors which we can say with confidence influenced a Senator's decision to vote for or against this bill. The coefficients reported and labeled ‘der of prob’ measure the derivative of the probability of a yes vote evaluated at the means of the independent variables in question. Thus, for example the coefficient for UNEMP in the top line of Table 1 should be interpreted as indicating that a one percentage point increase in a state's unemployment rate will cause a 5.89% increase in the probability that the Senator will vote for the bill. The result for DR, the party of the Senator, shows that in general Democrats are more apt to vote for protectionist policies than are Republicans. This is consistant with President Reagan's negative stand on the bill, and his threat to veto it should it pass. The amendment in question passed the Senate on 24 October 1985, by a vote of 54 for to 42 against, but the bill it was attached to has been postponed indefinitely. The House bill, which was passed on 10 October 1985 by a vote of 262 for to 159 against, was vetoed by Reagan on 17 December 1985. The results of the probit analysis for the House of Representatives are shown in Table 2. State employment data was used for the House as opposed to data for each voting district. This was done for three reasons. First, employment data is usually reported by state or by county. Since counties are often divided by congressional district boundaries, much personal judgement would be necessary to assign employment figures. Second, the most recent county industry employment data is from 1981, while the data used in this analysis is from 1984. Third, we feel that in general ‘logrolling’ is prevalent among a state's representatives. For this bill, the representatives from twenty six states voted as a block, and in all but six states one third or less of that state's representatives voted contrary to the majority. All of the probabilities are significant at the .05 confidence level. Representative's voting patterns are influenced by all of the included factors. When unionization is added to the equation, its coefficient is very small and negative although it is significant at the .05 confidence level. One would expect more significance here since there are more degrees of freedom for the House analysis than for that of the Senate. When the data from the House and Senate are pooled the results are similar to those of the House alone. The null hypothesis that the data cannot be pooled was tested using a χ 2 statistic with eight degrees of freedom. χ 2 =9.721, meaning that the null hypothesis is rejected. As in the Senate, the state unemployment rate and the percent employed in textiles are important influences on the Representative's vote, and Democrats in the House are more likely to vote for protectionist bills than Republicans. However, unlike the Senate, the percent of a Representative's campaign contributions that are donated by industry special interest groups has a significant effect on voting patterns, although the point estimates for the magnitudes of the influence are very similar in both cases. Seventy-four percent of the House received campaign contributions from these special interest groups, while only 54% of the Senate received contributions from these same sources. This is probably because only one third of the Senate was up for reelection during the time period considered, while the entire House was in the process of campaigning for reelection. Exports also play a role in influencing the probability of a ‘yes’ vote, reducing this probability as employment in export industries increases, but the magnitude of the coefficient is only 11% of that for textile employment. The significance of this variable in the House is probably due to fear of retaliation, expressed by both Democrats and Republicans. This variable was not significant in the Senate model, most likely because the Senate version excluded from the 1% import quota growth rate many countries who might have retaliated. Representatives appear to respond to a wider variety of constituent interests than do Senators. While Senators' voting patterns are only significantly influenced by their political affiliation, their state's unemployment rate and the importance of textiles to their state, the voting behavior of Representatives is influenced by these factors as well as the importance of exports to their state and campaign contributions by textile special interest groups. These results affirm the validity of the approach used by Baldwin and Coughlin. They differ from Baldwin who finds exports are not a significant influence on the House, and from Coughlin, who does not include export employment as an explanitory variable or analyze the differences in voting patterns between the House and the Senate. Copyright Martinus Nijhoff Publishers 1987

Suggested Citation

  • Suzanne Tosini & Edward Tower, 1987. "The textile bill of 1985: The determinants of congressional voting patterns," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 54(1), pages 19-25, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:54:y:1987:i:1:p:19-25
    DOI: 10.1007/BF00123802
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/BF00123802
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/BF00123802?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Brock, William A & Magee, Stephen P, 1978. "The Economics of Special Interest Politics: The Case of the Tariff," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 68(2), pages 246-250, May.
    2. J.M. Finger & H. Keith Hall & Douglas R. Nelson, 2002. "The Political Economy of Administered Protection," Chapters, in: Institutions and Trade Policy, chapter 8, pages 81-95, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    3. Kalt, Joseph P & Zupan, Mark A, 1984. "Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 74(3), pages 279-300, June.
    4. Coughlin, Cletus C, 1985. "Domestic Content Legislation: House Voting and the Economic Theory of Regulation," Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International, vol. 23(3), pages 437-448, July.
    5. Pugel, Thomas A & Walter, Ingo, 1985. "U.S. Corporate Interests and the Political Economy of Trade Policy," The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 67(3), pages 465-473, August.
    6. Feigenbaum, Susan & Ortiz, Henry & Willett, Thomas D, 1985. "Protectionist Pressures and Aggregate Economic Conditions: Comment [Pressures for Protectionism: An Empirical Analysis]," Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International, vol. 23(1), pages 175-182, January.
    7. Takacs, Wendy E, 1981. "Pressures for Protectionism: An Empirical Analysis," Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International, vol. 19(4), pages 687-693, October.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Richard T. Cupitt & Euel Elliott, 1994. "Schattschneider Revisited: Senate Voting On The Smoot‐Hawley Tariff Act Of 1930," Economics and Politics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 6(3), pages 187-199, November.
    2. William J. Byrd & John A. Dove, 2021. "Dismantling the south-west coalition: further evidence of distributive politics in preemption legislation," Economics of Governance, Springer, vol. 22(3), pages 193-214, September.
    3. Baban Hasnat & Charles Callahan, III, 2004. "The Determinants of US Congressional Voting on the Trade and Development Act of 2000," International Journal of Business and Economics, School of Management Development, Feng Chia University, Taichung, Taiwan, vol. 3(1), pages 35-44, April.
    4. Grossman, Gene M & Helpman, Elhanan, 1995. "Trade Wars and Trade Talks," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 103(4), pages 675-708, August.
    5. Freille, Sebastián, 2015. "Do private campaing contributions affect electoral results? An examination of Argentine national elections," MPRA Paper 65455, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    6. Boadu, Frederick O. & Thompson, Marla R., 1993. "The Political Economy Of The U.S.-Mexico Free Trade Agreement: Analysis Of The Congressional Fast Track Vote," Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, Southern Agricultural Economics Association, vol. 25(2), pages 1-9, December.
    7. Marshall Medoff, 1989. "Constituencies, ideology, and the demand for abortion legislation," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 60(2), pages 185-191, February.
    8. Eline Poelmans & John A. Dove & Jason E. Taylor, 2018. "The politics of beer: analysis of the congressional votes on the beer bill of 1933," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 174(1), pages 81-106, January.
    9. Potters, Jan & Sloof, Randolph, 1996. "Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 12(3), pages 403-442, November.
    10. Gavious, Arieh & Mizrahi, Shlomo, 2002. "Maximizing political efficiency via electoral cycles: An optimal control model," European Journal of Operational Research, Elsevier, vol. 141(1), pages 186-199, August.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Michael P. Leidy, 1994. "Trade Policy And Indirect Rent Seeking: A Synthesis Of Recent Work†," Economics and Politics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 6(2), pages 97-118, July.
    2. Chung, Jae W., 1999. "Insights Into Trade Protection under U.S. Trade Remedy Laws," Journal of Policy Modeling, Elsevier, vol. 21(3), pages 375-387, May.
    3. Jae W. Chung, 1998. "Effects of U.S. Trade Remedy Law Enforcement under Uncertainty: The Case of Steel," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 65(1), pages 151-159, July.
    4. Rausser, Gordon C. & de Gorter, Harry, 1988. "Endogenizing Policy In Models Of Agricultural Markets," 1988 Annual Meeting, August 1-3, Knoxville, Tennessee 270460, American Agricultural Economics Association (New Name 2008: Agricultural and Applied Economics Association).
    5. Aksel Erbahar & Yuan Zi, 2015. "Cascading Trade Protection: Theory and Evidence from the U.S," CTEI Working Papers series 04-2015, Centre for Trade and Economic Integration, The Graduate Institute.
    6. Fredriksson, Per G. & Vollebergh, Herman R. J. & Dijkgraaf, Elbert, 2004. "Corruption and energy efficiency in OECD countries: theory and evidence," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Elsevier, vol. 47(2), pages 207-231, March.
    7. Hadi Salehi Esfahani & Stephanie Leaphart, 2000. "Estimating Trade Policy Models: An Empirical Study of Protection Policy in Turkey," Econometric Society World Congress 2000 Contributed Papers 0563, Econometric Society.
    8. Bruce A. Blonigen & Robert C. Feenstra, 1997. "Protectionist Threats and Foreign Direct Investment," NBER Chapters, in: The Effects of US Trade Protection and Promotion Policies, pages 55-80, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    9. Daniel Trefler, 2004. "The Long and Short of the Canada-U. S. Free Trade Agreement," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 94(4), pages 870-895, September.
    10. Mordechal Kreinin & Elias Dinopoulos, 1995. "Protection of industry," Open Economies Review, Springer, vol. 6(2), pages 179-196, April.
    11. Tansey, Michael & Raju, Sudhakar & Stellern, Michael, 2005. "Price controls, trade protectionism and political business cycles in the U.S. steel industry," Journal of Policy Modeling, Elsevier, vol. 27(9), pages 1097-1109, December.
    12. Robert Baldwin & Jeffrey Steagall, 1994. "An analysis of ITC decisions in antidumping, countervailing duty and safeguard cases," Review of World Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv), Springer;Institut für Weltwirtschaft (Kiel Institute for the World Economy), vol. 130(2), pages 290-308, June.
    13. Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore, 1990. "Politische Ökonomie des Protektionismus: Ein institutioneller Ansatz," Discussion Papers, Series II 109, University of Konstanz, Collaborative Research Centre (SFB) 178 "Internationalization of the Economy".
    14. Nelson, Douglas, 2006. "The political economy of antidumping: A survey," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 22(3), pages 554-590, September.
    15. Erbahar, Aksel & Zi, Yuan, 2017. "Cascading trade protection: Evidence from the US," Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol. 108(C), pages 274-299.
    16. Kokko, Ari & Gustavsson Tingvall, Patrik & Videnord, Josefin, 2017. "Which Antidumping Cases Reach the WTO?," Ratio Working Papers 286, The Ratio Institute.
    17. Le Breton, Michel & Salanie, Francois, 2003. "Lobbying under political uncertainty," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 87(12), pages 2589-2610, December.
    18. Daowei Zhang & David Laband, 2005. "From Senators to the President: Solve the lumber problem or else," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 123(3), pages 393-410, June.
    19. Potters, Jan & Sloof, Randolph, 1996. "Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 12(3), pages 403-442, November.
    20. Richard Damania & Per Fredriksson & Thomas Osang, 2004. "Collusion, Collective Action and Protection: Theory and Evidence," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 121(3), pages 279-308, February.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:54:y:1987:i:1:p:19-25. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.