IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ekd/010027/10240.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Factor-Specific Technology Choice

Author

Listed:
  • Jakub Growiec

Abstract

The purpose of this article is to provide a detailed treatment of a static, two-dimensional problem of optimal factor-specific technology choice. In such a problem, the decision maker faces a menu of local technologies which depend on the quantity of the two factors and their respective quality (i.e., unit productivity). The menu features a trade-off insofar as choosing higher quality of one factor comes at the cost of reducing the quality of the other one. The decision maker is allowed to select her preferred technology, in order to maximize total output/profit/utility, for all configurations of factor quantities. The aggregate function is then constructed as an envelope of local functions. Decision problems with this structure may arise in firms which contemplate not just about the demand for production factors -- such as capital and labor -- but also about the degree of their technological augmentation (Atkinson & Stiglitz 1969, Basu & Weil 1998, Caselli & Coleman 2006). Mathematically equivalent problems are also faced by consumers who are allowed to decide both about the quantity and quality of the demanded goods, as well as by workers (or managers) who allocate their limited endowments of time/effort across two alternative tasks. Hence, despite being motivated primarily by the earlier contributions to the theory of economic growth and factor-augmenting technical change (e.g., Basu & Weil 1998, Acemoglu 2003, Jones 2005, Caselli & Coleman 2006), the appeal of the current paper is in fact much broader. The class of problems which we solve here has applications both in micro- and macroeconomics, and they can be viewed both as producer and consumer problems. Factor-specific technology choice problems of the type studied here are useful, in particular, for addressing issues related to natural resources, human capital and capital--skill complementarity, industrial organization, international trade, labor markets, sectoral change, consumption patterns, social welfare, and so on. Interesting results have already been obtained for certain specific cases of the factor-specific technology choice problem. First, it has been demonstrated that when the technology menu has the Cobb--Douglas form (which may arise, among other cases, if factor-specific ideas are independently Pareto--distributed; Jones 2005) or if the local function is of such form (Growiec 2008a), then the aggregate function also inherits the Cobb--Douglas form. Second, combining a local function of a CES or a minimum (Leontief) form and a CES technology menu yields an aggregate CES function (Growiec 2008b, Matveenko 2010, Growiec 2011,Leon-Ledesma & Satchi 2016). Third, a broader treatment of the properties of factor-specific technology choice problems with a minimum (Leontief) local function, including their intriguing duality properties, has been provided by Rubinov & Glover (1998), Matveenko (1997), Matveenko (2010), Matveenko & Matveenko (2015). While instructive, the minimum function is however an extreme case, particularly problematic when interpreted as a utility function. Fourth, a few promising results for the general factor-specific technology choice problem with an implicitly specified technology menu have also been provided in section 2.3 of Leon-Ledesma & Satchi (2016). Notwithstanding these important special cases, the literature thus far has not devised a general theoretical framework allowing to analyze the factor-specific technology choice problem in its generality. The key contribution of this article is to put forward such a general theory -- one which would frame all these earlier results in a unique encompassing structure. We find that a unique optimal factor-specific technology choice exists for any homothetic local function $F$ and technology menu $G$. Plugging this choice into the local function $F$ leads to a unique homogeneous (constant returns to scale) aggregate function $\Phi$, which may then be transformed to a homothetic form by an arbitrary monotone transformation. We also find that (i) the shape of the aggregate function $\Phi$ depends non-trivially both on $F$ and $G$ unless one of them is of the Cobb--Douglas form, and (ii) the aggregate function $\Phi$ offers more substitution possibilities (i.e., has less curvature) than the local function $F$ unless the optimal technology choice is independent of factor endowments, which happens only if $F$ is Cobb--Douglas or $G$ follows a maximum function. Our second contribution is to construct and solve the dual problem (in a well-defined generalized sense of duality) where, for every technology, the decision maker maximizes output/profit/utility subject to a requirement of producing a predefined quantity with the aggregate technology $\Phi$. Then, by plugging these optimal factor choices into the local function $F$, we obtain the technology menu $G$ as an envelope. The results are fully analogous. At this stage, the duality property also allows us to provide an additional contribution. Namely, we find that in the optimum, partial elasticities of all three objects -- the local function $F$, the technology menu $G$ and the aggregate function $\Phi$ -- are all equal. We then identify a clear-cut, economically interpretable relationship between their curvatures, giving rise to interesting qualitative implications on concavity/convexity and gross complementarity/substitutability along the three functions. The assumption of homotheticity which we make throughout the analysis, while shared by bulk of the associated literature, does not come without costs. The key limitation is due to Bergson's theorem (Burk 1936) which states that every homothetic function that is also additively separable (either directly or after a monotone transformation) must be either of the Cobb--Douglas or CES functional form. Hence, when one wants to go beyond the CES framework, one must either give up homotheticity (e.g., Zhelobodko et al. 2012) or additive separability (e.g., Revankar 1971, Growiec & Muck 2016, this paper). It follows that all the non-CES cases which are covered by the current study but have not been discussed before, cannot be written down as additively separable. We also devote a separate section of the paper to study the link between the technology menu and the distributions of ideas. Indeed, part of the associated literature derives the technology menu as a level curve of a certain joint distribution of ideas (unit factor productivities) where the marginal idea distributions are either independent (Jones 2005, Growiec 2008b) or dependent following a certain copula (Growiec 2008a). Extending these studies, we show that such ``probabilistic'' construction of the technology menu may place a restriction on the considered class of functions $G$, potentially reducing it to the Cobb--Douglas or CES form because of their homotheticity and additive separability (after a monotone transformation). To show this, we adapt Bergson's theorem to the case of copulas, and particularly Archimedean ones.

Suggested Citation

  • Jakub Growiec, 2017. "Factor-Specific Technology Choice," EcoMod2017 10240, EcoMod.
  • Handle: RePEc:ekd:010027:10240
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://ecomod.net/system/files/factor-specific-technology%2013.02.2017.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Other versions of this item:

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Moysan, Gwenaël & Senouci, Mehdi, 2016. "A note on 2-input neoclassical production functions," Journal of Mathematical Economics, Elsevier, vol. 67(C), pages 80-86.
    2. Abram Burk, 1936. "Real Income, Expenditure Proportionality, and Frisch's "New Methods of Measuring Marginal Utility"," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 4(1), pages 33-52.
    3. Jan Witajewski-Baltvilks, 2015. "Can endogenous technology choices explain wage inequality dynamics?," IBS Working Papers 15/2015, Instytut Badan Strukturalnych.
    4. Smulders, Sjak & de Nooij, Michiel, 2003. "The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth," Resource and Energy Economics, Elsevier, vol. 25(1), pages 59-79, February.
    5. Growiec, Jakub & McAdam, Peter & Mućk, Jakub, 2018. "Endogenous labor share cycles: Theory and evidence," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 87(C), pages 74-93.
    6. Susanto Basu & David N. Weil, 1998. "Appropriate Technology and Growth," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 113(4), pages 1025-1054.
    7. Piyabha Kongsamut & Sergio Rebelo & Danyang Xie, 2001. "Beyond Balanced Growth," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 68(4), pages 869-882.
    8. Evgeny Zhelobodko & Sergey Kokovin & Mathieu Parenti & Jacques‐François Thisse, 2012. "Monopolistic Competition: Beyond the Constant Elasticity of Substitution," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 80(6), pages 2765-2784, November.
    9. Miguel A. León-Ledesma & Peter McAdam & Alpo Willman, 2010. "Identifying the Elasticity of Substitution with Biased Technical Change," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 100(4), pages 1330-1357, September.
    10. Growiec, Jakub & Mućk, Jakub, 2020. "Isoelastic Elasticity Of Substitution Production Functions," Macroeconomic Dynamics, Cambridge University Press, vol. 24(7), pages 1597-1634, October.
    11. John Duffy & Chris Papageorgiou & Fidel Perez-Sebastian, 2004. "Capital-Skill Complementarity? Evidence from a Panel of Countries," The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 86(1), pages 327-344, February.
    12. K. J. Arrow & M.D. Intriligator (ed.), 1993. "Handbook of Mathematical Economics," Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Elsevier, edition 4, volume 2, number 2.
    13. Timo Boppart, 2014. "Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model With Relative Price Effects and Non‐Gorman Preferences," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 82, pages 2167-2196, November.
    14. JosÉ Figueira & Salvatore Greco & Matthias Ehrogott, 2005. "Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: State of the Art Surveys," International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, Springer, number 978-0-387-23081-8, September.
    15. Vladimir Matveenko, 2010. "Anatomy of production functions: a technological menu and a choice of the best technology," Economics Bulletin, AccessEcon, vol. 30(3), pages 1906-1913.
    16. Revankar, Nagesh S, 1971. "A Class of Variable Elasticity of Substitution Production Functions," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 39(1), pages 61-71, January.
    17. Diewert, W.E., 1993. "Duality approaches to microeconomic theory," Handbook of Mathematical Economics, in: K. J. Arrow & M.D. Intriligator (ed.), Handbook of Mathematical Economics, edition 4, volume 2, chapter 12, pages 535-599, Elsevier.
    18. Growiec, Jakub, 2013. "A microfoundation for normalized CES production functions with factor-augmenting technical change," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 37(11), pages 2336-2350.
    19. Per Krusell & Lee E. Ohanian & JosÈ-Victor RÌos-Rull & Giovanni L. Violante, 2000. "Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 68(5), pages 1029-1054, September.
    20. Mr. Sergio Rebelo & Ms. Piyabha Kongsamut & Danyang Xie, 2001. "Beyond Balanced Growth," IMF Working Papers 2001/085, International Monetary Fund.
    21. Bretschger, Lucas & Smulders, Sjak, 2012. "Sustainability and substitution of exhaustible natural resources," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 36(4), pages 536-549.
    22. Andrei Matveenko & Vladimir Matveenko, 2014. "Curvature and the Elasticity of Substitution: What Is the Link? Project," Montenegrin Journal of Economics, Economic Laboratory for Transition Research (ELIT), vol. 10(2), pages 7-20.
    23. Daron Acemoglu, 2002. "Directed Technical Change," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 69(4), pages 781-809.
    24. H. Uzawa, 1961. "Neutral Inventions and the Stability of Growth Equilibrium," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 28(2), pages 117-124.
    25. Daron Acemoglu, 2003. "Labor- And Capital-Augmenting Technical Change," Journal of the European Economic Association, MIT Press, vol. 1(1), pages 1-37, March.
    26. de La Grandville, Olivier, 1989. "In Quest of the Slutsky Diamond," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 79(3), pages 468-481, June.
    27. Kelvin J. Lancaster, 1966. "A New Approach to Consumer Theory," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 74, pages 132-132.
    28. Olivier de La Grandville & Rainer Klump, 2000. "Economic Growth and the Elasticity of Substitution: Two Theorems and Some Suggestions," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 90(1), pages 282-291, March.
    29. Samuel S. Kortum, 1997. "Research, Patenting, and Technological Change," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 65(6), pages 1389-1420, November.
    30. Francesco Caselli & Wilbur John Coleman II, 2006. "The World Technology Frontier," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 96(3), pages 499-522, June.
    31. Growiec, Jakub, 2008. "Production functions and distributions of unit factor productivities: Uncovering the link," Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 101(1), pages 87-90, October.
    32. Charles I. Jones, 2005. "The Shape of Production Functions and the Direction of Technical Change," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 120(2), pages 517-549.
    33. Rainer Klump & Peter McAdam & Alpo Willman, 2012. "The Normalized Ces Production Function: Theory And Empirics," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 26(5), pages 769-799, December.
    34. Moysan, Gwenaël & Senouci, Mehdi, 2016. "A note on 2-input neoclassical production functions," Journal of Mathematical Economics, Elsevier, vol. 67(C), pages 80-86.
    35. Jakub Growiec, 2008. "A new class of production functions and an argument against purely labor‐augmenting technical change," International Journal of Economic Theory, The International Society for Economic Theory, vol. 4(4), pages 483-502, December.
    36. Rader, Trout, 1972. "Theory of Microeconomics," Elsevier Monographs, Elsevier, edition 1, number 9780125750509.
    37. Nakamura, Hideki & Nakamura, Masakatsu, 2008. "Constant-Elasticity-Of-Substitution Production Function," Macroeconomic Dynamics, Cambridge University Press, vol. 12(5), pages 694-701, November.
    38. Nakamura, Hideki, 2009. "Micro-foundation for a constant elasticity of substitution production function through mechanization," Journal of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, vol. 31(3), pages 464-472, September.
    39. Atkinson, Anthony B & Stiglitz, Joseph E, 1969. "A New View of Technological Change," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 79(315), pages 573-578, September.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Armando Sánchez-Vargas & José Manuel Márquez-Estrada & Eric Hernández-Ramírez, 2023. "Uncovering the Link Between the Theoretical and Probabilistic Models of the Global Production Function: A Copula Approach," Journal of Quantitative Economics, Springer;The Indian Econometric Society (TIES), vol. 21(2), pages 289-315, June.
    2. Guimarães, Luís & Mazeda Gil, Pedro, 2022. "Explaining the Labor Share: Automation Vs Labor Market Institutions," Labour Economics, Elsevier, vol. 75(C).
    3. Irmen Andreas, 2020. "Endogenous task-based technical change—factor scarcity and factor prices," Economics and Business Review, Sciendo, vol. 6(2), pages 81-118, June.
    4. Michael Knoblach & Fabian Stöckl, 2020. "What Determines The Elasticity Of Substitution Between Capital And Labor? A Literature Review," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 34(4), pages 847-875, September.
    5. Jakub Growiec, 2019. "The Hardware–Software Model: A New Conceptual Framework of Production, R&D, and Growth with AI," Working Paper series 19-18, Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis.
    6. Kemnitz, Alexander & Knoblach, Michael, 2020. "Endogenous sigma-augmenting technological change: An R&D-based approach," CEPIE Working Papers 02/20, Technische Universität Dresden, Center of Public and International Economics (CEPIE).
    7. Lin, Justin Yifu & Liu, Zhengwen & Zhang, Bo, 2023. "Endowment, technology choice, and industrial upgrading," Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Elsevier, vol. 65(C), pages 364-381.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Michael Knoblach & Fabian Stöckl, 2020. "What Determines The Elasticity Of Substitution Between Capital And Labor? A Literature Review," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 34(4), pages 847-875, September.
    2. Growiec, Jakub & Mućk, Jakub, 2020. "Isoelastic Elasticity Of Substitution Production Functions," Macroeconomic Dynamics, Cambridge University Press, vol. 24(7), pages 1597-1634, October.
    3. Growiec, Jakub, 2013. "A microfoundation for normalized CES production functions with factor-augmenting technical change," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 37(11), pages 2336-2350.
    4. Growiec, Jakub, 2013. "Factor-augmenting technology choice and monopolistic competition," Journal of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, vol. 38(PA), pages 86-94.
    5. Temple, Jonathan, 2012. "The calibration of CES production functions," Journal of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, vol. 34(2), pages 294-303.
    6. Growiec, Jakub & McAdam, Peter & Mućk, Jakub, 2018. "Endogenous labor share cycles: Theory and evidence," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 87(C), pages 74-93.
    7. Jakub Growiec, 2008. "A new class of production functions and an argument against purely labor‐augmenting technical change," International Journal of Economic Theory, The International Society for Economic Theory, vol. 4(4), pages 483-502, December.
    8. Kemnitz, Alexander & Knoblach, Michael, 2020. "Endogenous sigma-augmenting technological change: An R&D-based approach," CEPIE Working Papers 02/20, Technische Universität Dresden, Center of Public and International Economics (CEPIE).
    9. Rainer Klump & Peter McAdam & Alpo Willman, 2012. "The Normalized Ces Production Function: Theory And Empirics," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 26(5), pages 769-799, December.
    10. Lin, Justin Yifu & Liu, Zhengwen & Zhang, Bo, 2023. "Endowment, technology choice, and industrial upgrading," Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Elsevier, vol. 65(C), pages 364-381.
    11. Xue, Jianpo & Yip, Chong K., 2013. "Aggregate elasticity of substitution and economic growth: A synthesis," Journal of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, vol. 38(PA), pages 60-75.
    12. Miguel A. Leon-Ledesma & Mathan Satchi, 2015. "Appropriate Technology and the Labour Share," Studies in Economics 1505, School of Economics, University of Kent, revised Nov 2016.
    13. Miguel A León-Ledesma & Mathan Satchi, 2019. "Appropriate Technology and Balanced Growth," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 86(2), pages 807-835.
    14. Miguel A León-Ledesma & Peter McAdam & Alpo Willman, 2012. "Non-Balanced Growth and Production Technology Estimation," Studies in Economics 1204, School of Economics, University of Kent.
    15. Miguel A. Leon-Ledesma & Mathan Satchi, 2010. "A Note on Balanced Growth with a less than unitary Elasticity of Substitution," Studies in Economics 1007, School of Economics, University of Kent.
    16. Armando Sánchez-Vargas & José Manuel Márquez-Estrada & Eric Hernández-Ramírez, 2023. "Uncovering the Link Between the Theoretical and Probabilistic Models of the Global Production Function: A Copula Approach," Journal of Quantitative Economics, Springer;The Indian Econometric Society (TIES), vol. 21(2), pages 289-315, June.
    17. Daron Acemoglu & Veronica Guerrieri, 2008. "Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 116(3), pages 467-498, June.
    18. Clemens Struck & Adnan Velic, 2017. "Automation, New Technology, and Non-Homothetic Preferences," Trinity Economics Papers tep1217, Trinity College Dublin, Department of Economics.
    19. Jakub Mućk & Peter McAdam & Jakub Growiec, 2018. "Will The “True” Labor Share Stand Up? An Applied Survey On Labor Share Measures," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 32(4), pages 961-984, September.
    20. Paul, Saumik, 2019. "Labor Income Share Dynamics with Variable Elasticity of Substitution," IZA Discussion Papers 12418, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Theoretical study; Growth; General equilibrium modeling (CGE);
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • C62 - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods - - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling - - - Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium
    • D11 - Microeconomics - - Household Behavior - - - Consumer Economics: Theory
    • D21 - Microeconomics - - Production and Organizations - - - Firm Behavior: Theory
    • E21 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics - - Consumption, Saving, Production, Employment, and Investment - - - Consumption; Saving; Wealth
    • E23 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics - - Consumption, Saving, Production, Employment, and Investment - - - Production
    • O47 - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth - - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity - - - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity; Cross-Country Output Convergence

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ekd:010027:10240. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Theresa Leary (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ecomoea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.