IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ehs/wpaper/5013.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Do frontiers give or do frontiers take? The case of intercontinental trade in France at the end of the Ancien Régime

Author

Listed:
  • Guillaume Daudin

    (OFCE)

Abstract

"In the eighteenth century, the trading activities of Nantes, Bordeaux, Marseilles and Rouen expanded much faster than the rest of the French economy. The usual trade analysis tools suggest that their trade had no effect on the French economy, as the most dynamic activity of these harbours merely used France as a warehouse between the West Indies and the rest of Europe. This paper examines the role of this maritime frontier in the domestic capital accumulation. Many authors asserted that the relations between European nations and the rest of the world played a great role in the “primitive accumulation” of capital before the Industrial Revolution. Their statements are controversial. Most economic historians would agree with Patrick O’Brien’s view as it is expressed in his 1982 paper : profits from the “periphery” were simply too small to have played a major role in European growth. This paper first transposes O’Brien’s computation to the case of France at the end of the Ancien Régime. Three estimations are needed: one of the annual rate of profit; one of the amount of trade; and one of the amount of capital invested for each unit of trade. My estimation for the annual rate of profits is 6.25% on a three-year rotation of capital, i.e. a rate of profit of 20% on the whole rotation of capital . For reasons developed elsewhere, I believe Arnould offers us the best measure of trade : he indicates the size of intercontinental French trade to be 610 million livres tournois (approximately £25 million) in 1787 . 125 ship investment accounts allow me to estimate the ratio between the amount of capital invested and the value of exported cargo to be 225%. Based on these numbers, annual French profits from international trade can be estimated at 142 million livres tournois. Computing profits is not enough, however. One needs to compute the extra profits provided by investment in intercontinental trade compared to investment in the domestic economy. Following the recommendations of Barbara Solow – and under the hypotheses that the remuneration of domestic capital was 4.5% and that 25% of French income went to capital, 15% to land and the rest to labour – this paper assesses that the existence of the intercontinental sector represented an additional income of between 1.5% and 2% for the French economy at the end of the Ancien Régime. The intercontinental sector effect was small compared to total French income. Yet, its existence had a redistributive role, mainly in the favour of capital. Through this redistributive role, it played a role in determining the saving rate and the capital accumulation rate. Under reasonable hypothesis, extra savings accruing from the existence of intercontinental trade represented 5-6.3% of total French savings. That increased the growth rate of the economy by 6-7.6% (i.e. 0.036-0.046 percentage points). Even if the intercontinental sector was a dynamic sector that “pulled” the rest of the economy, its direct role was small. This paper suggests that another, indirect, role may have been more important. The intercontinental sector encouraged capital accumulation in the domestic economy rather than irrigated it. Over-investment was a much more remote possibility in world trade than in one country’s domestic economy. By offering a way out of decreasing returns to capital, the intercontinental trade sector encouraged capital accumulation in the whole economy, in the same way as “heart of growth” sectors in AK-type growth models do. Actually, the usual notion of a high-profit sector “irrigating” the rest of the economy with its profits is difficult to justify: one expects capital to move to high-profit sectors, not from them. Accordingly, there are indications that the profits from the intercontinental trade sector were kept there, even if this did not exclude some asset diversification directed toward geographically close industrial firms in which the utilisation of knowledge and social networks already accumulated in intercontinental trade was possible. In addition to keeping its capital, the intercontinental sector attracted entrepreneurs – and their financial, human and social capital stocks – from the interior economy. That – negative – attraction effect was counterbalanced by the encouragement to capital accumulation. However, it is possible to show that theoretically the net effect would have been very small if the intercontinental sector had become an enclave. Ironically, as French entrepreneurs have often been exposed for their lack of capitalist thriftiness, the fact that they used an important part of their income to consume French domestic goods prevented that and was as such a good thing."

Suggested Citation

  • Guillaume Daudin, 2005. "Do frontiers give or do frontiers take? The case of intercontinental trade in France at the end of the Ancien Régime," Working Papers 5013, Economic History Society.
  • Handle: RePEc:ehs:wpaper:5013
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://www.ehs.org.uk/dotAsset/9287357d-8007-4fb8-b2ce-1f0026f4b216.doc
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Other versions of this item:

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Daudin, Guillaume, 2004. "Profitability of Slave and Long-Distance Trading in Context: The Case of Eighteenth-Century France," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 64(1), pages 144-171, March.
    2. T.M. Devine, 1976. "The Colonial Trades and Industrial Investment in Scotland, c. 1700-1815," Economic History Review, Economic History Society, vol. 29(1), pages 1-13, February.
    3. Darity, William, 1985. "The Numbers Game and the Profitability of the British Trade in Slaves," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 45(3), pages 693-703, September.
    4. Robert M. Solow, 1956. "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 70(1), pages 65-94.
    5. Paul M. Romer, 1989. "Increasing Returns and New Developments in the Theory of Growth," NBER Working Papers 3098, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    6. Inikori, Joseph E., 1990. "The credit needs of the African trade and the development of the credit economy in England," Explorations in Economic History, Elsevier, vol. 27(2), pages 197-231, April.
    7. Coelho, Philip R. P., 1973. "The profitability of imperialism: The British experience in the West indies 1768-1772," Explorations in Economic History, Elsevier, vol. 10(3), pages 253-280.
    8. Robert Paul Thomas, 1968. "The Sugar Colonies of the Old Empire:Profit or Loss for Great Britain?," Economic History Review, Economic History Society, vol. 21(1), pages 30-45, April.
    9. Rebelo, Sergio, 1991. "Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 99(3), pages 500-521, June.
    10. Inikori, J. E., 1981. "Market Structure and the Profits of the British African Trade in the Late Eighteenth Century," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 41(4), pages 745-776, December.
    11. Eltis, David & Engerman, Stanley L., 2000. "The Importance of Slavery and the Slave Trade to Industrializing Britain," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 60(1), pages 123-144, March.
    12. Velde, François R. & Weir, David R., 1992. "The Financial Market and Government Debt Policy in France, 1746–1793," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 52(1), pages 1-39, March.
    13. Engerman, Stanley L., 1972. "The Slave Trade and British Capital Formation in the Eighteenth Century: A Comment on the Williams Thesis," Business History Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 46(4), pages 430-443, January.
    14. R. B. Sheridan, 1965. "The Wealth of Jamaica in the Eighteenth Century," Economic History Review, Economic History Society, vol. 18(2), pages 292-311, August.
    15. Guillaume Daudin, 2002. "The quality of slave trade investment in eighteenth century France," Documents de Travail de l'OFCE 2002-06, Observatoire Francais des Conjonctures Economiques (OFCE).
    16. Solow, Barbara L., 1985. "Caribbean slavery and British growth," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 17(1), pages 99-115.
    17. Thomas, Robert Paul & Bean, Richard Nelson, 1974. "The Fishers of Men: The Profits of the Slave Trade," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 34(4), pages 885-914, December.
    18. Jérôme Glachant, 1995. "Croissance et structure du système productif dans une économie log-linéaire," Annals of Economics and Statistics, GENES, issue 39, pages 33-66.
    19. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/691 is not listed on IDEAS
    20. Solow, Barbara L., 1985. "Caribbean slavery and British growth : The Eric Williams hypothesis," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 17(1-2), pages 99-115.
    21. Lucas, Robert Jr., 1988. "On the mechanics of economic development," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 22(1), pages 3-42, July.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Kevin H. O'Rourke, Leandro Prados de la Escosura and Guilllaume Daudin, 2008. "Trade and Empire, 1700-1870," The Institute for International Integration Studies Discussion Paper Series iiisdp249, IIIS.
    2. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/6149 is not listed on IDEAS
    3. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/684 is not listed on IDEAS
    4. Guillaume Daudin, 2006. "Profits du commerce intercontinental et croissance dans la France du xviiie siècle," Revue économique, Presses de Sciences-Po, vol. 57(3), pages 605-613.
    5. Guillaume Daudin, 2002. "The quality of slave trade investment in eighteenth century France," Documents de Travail de l'OFCE 2002-06, Observatoire Francais des Conjonctures Economiques (OFCE).

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/5l6uh8ogmqildh09h4dq825c3 is not listed on IDEAS
    2. Guillaume Daudin, 2006. "Profits du commerce intercontinental et croissance dans la France du xviiie siècle," Revue économique, Presses de Sciences-Po, vol. 57(3), pages 605-613.
    3. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/684 is not listed on IDEAS
    4. repec:spo:wpecon:info:hdl:2441/684 is not listed on IDEAS
    5. repec:hal:wpspec:info:hdl:2441/684 is not listed on IDEAS
    6. Daudin, Guillaume, 2004. "Profitability of Slave and Long-Distance Trading in Context: The Case of Eighteenth-Century France," The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, vol. 64(1), pages 144-171, March.
    7. Gregory Price & Warren Whatley, 2021. "Did profitable slave trading enable the expansion of empire?: The Asiento de Negros, the South Sea Company and the financial revolution in Great Britain," Cliometrica, Springer;Cliometric Society (Association Francaise de Cliométrie), vol. 15(3), pages 675-718, September.
    8. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/687 is not listed on IDEAS
    9. repec:spo:wpecon:info:hdl:2441/687 is not listed on IDEAS
    10. repec:hal:wpspec:info:hdl:2441/687 is not listed on IDEAS
    11. van de Klundert, T.C.M.J. & Smulders, J.A., 1991. "Reconstructing growth theory : A survey," Other publications TiSEM 19355c51-17eb-4d5d-aa66-b, Tilburg University, School of Economics and Management.
    12. Stephan Heblich & Stephen J. Redding & Hans-Joachim Voth, 2022. "Slavery and the British Industrial Revolution," CEP Discussion Papers dp1884, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
    13. Daron Acemoglu & Simon Johnson & James Robinson, 2005. "The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 95(3), pages 546-579, June.
    14. Dalton, John T. & Leung, Tin Cheuk, 2015. "Dispersion and distortions in the trans-Atlantic slave trade," Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol. 96(2), pages 412-425.
    15. Solow, Barbara L., 1985. "Caribbean slavery and British growth," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 17(1), pages 99-115.
    16. Schneider, Johannes & Ziesemer, Thomas, 1994. "What's New and What's Old in New Growth Theory: Endogenous Technology, Microfoundation, and Growth Rate Predictions," MPRA Paper 56132, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    17. Rao, B. Bhaskara, 2010. "Estimates of the steady state growth rates for selected Asian countries with an extended Solow model," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 27(1), pages 46-53, January.
    18. Prof. Dr. Adem KALCA & Resc. Assist. Atakan DURMAZ, 2012. "Diaspora As The Instrument Of Humane Capital," International Journal of Business and Social Research, LAR Center Press, vol. 2(5), pages 94-104, October.
    19. Carine Nourry, 2012. "Dasgupta, D.: Modern growth theory," Journal of Economics, Springer, vol. 105(1), pages 97-100, January.
    20. Benjamin Montmartin & Nadine Massard, 2015. "Is Financial Support For Private R&D Always Justified? A Discussion Based On The Literature On Growth," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 29(3), pages 479-505, July.
    21. Matthias Firgo & Peter Mayerhofer, 2015. "Wissens-Spillovers und regionale Entwicklung - welche strukturpolitische Ausrichtung optimiert des Wachstum?," Working Paper Reihe der AK Wien - Materialien zu Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 144, Kammer für Arbeiter und Angestellte für Wien, Abteilung Wirtschaftswissenschaft und Statistik.
    22. Marco Alfò & Lorenzo Carbonari & Giovanni Trovato, 2020. "On the Effects of Taxation on Growth: an Empirical Assessment," CEIS Research Paper 480, Tor Vergata University, CEIS, revised 08 May 2020.
    23. Michalis Nikiforos, 2020. "Demand, Distribution, Productivity, Structural Change, and (Secular?) Stagnation," Economics Working Paper Archive wp_945, Levy Economics Institute.
    24. Sushil Kumar Haldar, 2009. "Economic Growth in India Revisited," South Asia Economic Journal, Institute of Policy Studies of Sri Lanka, vol. 10(1), pages 105-126, January.
    25. Barro, Robert J, 1990. "Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 98(5), pages 103-126, October.
    26. Haytham Y.M. Ewaida, 2017. "The Impact of Sovereign Debt on Growth: An Empirical Study on GIIPS versus JUUSD Countries," European Research Studies Journal, European Research Studies Journal, vol. 0(2A), pages 607-633.
    27. Turnovsky, S., 2000. "Growth in an Open Economy: some Recent Developments," Papers 5, Warwick - Development Economics Research Centre.

    More about this item

    JEL classification:

    • N00 - Economic History - - General - - - General

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ehs:wpaper:5013. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Chair Public Engagement Committe (currently David Higgins - Newcastle) (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ehsukea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.