IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/ucp/tpolec/doi10.1086-683363.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Raising Revenue by Limiting Tax Expenditures

Author

Listed:
  • Martin Feldstein

Abstract

The prospect of very large future deficits and a rapidly increasing national debt is an important fiscal challenge for the United States. Limiting those deficits, and therefore the growth of the national debt, requires slowing the growth of the retirement and health programs. Additional tax revenue could contribute to that process. Limiting tax expenditures would raise revenue without increasing marginal tax rates. It would also be equivalent to reducing government spending now done as subsidies through the tax code for a wide range of household spending and income. An effective way of limiting tax expenditures would be a cap on the total tax reduction in tax liabilities that each individual can achieve by the use of deductions and exclusions.The national debt of the United States is now 74% of GDP, double what it was a decade ago. The current annual deficit of about three percent means that the debt will grow at about the same pace as nominal gross domestic product (GDP), keeping the ratio of debt to GDP unchanged. Although that is likely to continue for the next several years, the Congressional Budget Office has recently warned us that the debt ratio will start rising again and will grow to very high levels during the CBO's long-term forecast period (Congressional Budget Office 2014).More specifically, under the "extended baseline," the CBO projects that the debt to GDP ratio will rise during the next two decades to more than 100% of GDP. When the CBO drops some of the unrealistic assumptions that are required to be used in its baseline analysis, the forecasts in its "alternative fiscal scenario" show the debt rising to as much as 183% of GDP in 2039. The rising debt levels reflect the greater interest payments on the national debt and the increased cost of the middle-class health and retirement transfer programs. Limiting and reversing the rise in the national debt requires only relatively small decreases in annual deficit ratios. If real GDP grows at 2.5% and inflation is 2%, an annual deficit of 4.5% of GDP will cause the national debt to rise to 100% of GDP, but lowering the deficit to 2% of GDP will reverse the direction of the debt, causing it to decline to less than 50% of GDP.There is little scope for reducing the deficit by cutting spending on the annually appropriated "discretionary" programs. While there is no doubt of substantial waste in many programs, total outlays for nondefense discretionary programs is now just 3.4% of GDP and is projected to decline to 2.5% of GDP in 2024. Similarly, the defense programs are projected to decline to just 2.7% of GDP in 2024. Therefore, reducing the annual deficit requires some combination of slower growth of the retiree and health programs and increases in tax revenue.Tax rates have continued to rise in the years since the Tax Reform Act of 1986. That legislation reduced the top marginal tax rate to 28%. Since then the top personal income tax rate has increased to 40%. An additional tax increase on investment income was part of the Affordable Care Act, and the overall payroll tax on wage and salary income was increased when the old ceiling on income subject to the 2.9% Medicare tax was completely abolished.It is a central tenet of public economics that raising marginal tax rates increases the distorting effects of the tax system and thus the deadweight loss to the economy.Fortunately, it is possible to increase revenue without raising marginal tax rates. The key is to limit the reductions in tax revenue that result from the use of tax rules that substitute for direct government spending.Some examples will illustrate the nature of these "tax expenditures." If I buy a hybrid car or a solar panel for my house, the government rewards me with a subsidy payment. The subsidy does not take the form of a check from the government, but of a reduction in my tax liability. If I pay more in mortgage interest or in local property taxes, the government subsidizes my spending by allowing those expenses to be deducted in calculating my taxable income and therefore my tax liability.According to the Joint Committee on Taxation, the tax expenditure subsidies in the personal income tax code reduces revenue this year by approximately $1.6 trillion (Joint Committee on Taxation 2014). Those tax rules (especially the exclusion of employer payments for health insurance) also reduce the income that is subject to the payroll tax, leading to an additional loss of government revenue.Eliminating any of the tax expenditures or limiting their use would shrink the size of the annual deficits. Although the effect would show up on the revenue side of the government budget, that is just an accounting convention. In terms of real economic impact, limiting tax expenditures should be viewed as a reduction in government spending.The ability to frame tax expenditures as either revenue increases or spending decreases should make limiting tax expenditures appeal to those Republicans who want to reduce government spending as well as to those Democrats who want to use additional revenue to help shrink fiscal deficits. Some of the revenue produced by limiting tax expenditures could also be used to reduce marginal tax rates.Any attempt to limit a particular tax expenditure will be resisted by those who now benefit from it. That suggests that a comprehensive approach may be more politically feasible because no group of taxpayers will feel that they have been unfairly singled out. It also suggests that it would be politically difficult to eliminate completely any of the major tax expenditures. Instead, the analysis in this paper focuses on a method of limiting the extent to which each individual can benefit by using the full set of current tax expenditures.The first section describes a potential basic cap on the benefit that individuals can receive from an extensive set of tax expenditures. Section II discusses several features of using such an overall cap. The third section examines several variations of the basic cap. Section IV considers two alternatives to the cap stated as a percentage of GDP: limiting the overall dollar amount of deductions and limiting the benefit of deductions and exclusions to the 28% marginal tax rate. There is a brief concluding section.

Suggested Citation

  • Martin Feldstein, 2015. "Raising Revenue by Limiting Tax Expenditures," Tax Policy and the Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 29(1), pages 1-11.
  • Handle: RePEc:ucp:tpolec:doi:10.1086/683363
    DOI: 10.1086/683363
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/683363
    Download Restriction: Access to the online full text or PDF requires a subscription.

    File URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/683363
    Download Restriction: Access to the online full text or PDF requires a subscription.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1086/683363?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to look for a different version below or search for a different version of it.

    Other versions of this item:

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Congressional Budget Office, 2014. "The 2014 Long-Term Budget Outlook," Reports 45471, Congressional Budget Office.
    2. Congressional Budget Office, 2014. "The 2014 Long-Term Budget Outlook," Reports 45471, Congressional Budget Office.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Steven J. Davis, 2015. "Regulatory Complexity and Policy Uncertainty: Headwinds of Our Own Making," Economics Working Papers 15118, Hoover Institution, Stanford University.
    2. Salvador Barrios & Serena Fatica & Diego Martinez-Lopez & Gilles Mourre, 2018. "The Fiscal Effects of Work-related Tax Expenditures in Europe," Public Finance Review, , vol. 46(5), pages 793-820, September.
    3. Dabla-Norris, Era & Lima, Frederico, 2023. "Macroeconomic effects of tax rate and base changes: Evidence from fiscal consolidations," European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 153(C).
    4. Martin Fochmann & Frank Hechtner & Tobias Kölle & Michael Overesch, 2021. "Combating overreporting of deductions in tax returns: prefilling and restricting the deductibility of expenditures," Journal of Business Economics, Springer, vol. 91(7), pages 935-964, September.
    5. Rooney Patrick & Zarins Sasha & Bergdoll Jon & Osili Una, 2020. "The Impact of Five Different Tax Policy Changes on Household Giving in the United States," Nonprofit Policy Forum, De Gruyter, vol. 11(4), pages 1-18, December.
    6. Abdul Aziz Bin Karia, 2021. "Are there any turning points for external debt in Malaysia? Case of adaptive neuro-fuzzy inference systems model," Journal of Economic Structures, Springer;Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS), vol. 10(1), pages 1-16, December.
    7. Emile Cammeraat & Ernesto Crivelli, 2020. "Toward a Comprehensive Tax Reform for Italy," IMF Working Papers 2020/037, International Monetary Fund.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Hanming Fang & Qing Gong, 2017. "Detecting Potential Overbilling in Medicare Reimbursement via Hours Worked," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 107(2), pages 562-591, February.
    2. Duncan Ermini Leaf & Bryan Tysinger & Dana P. Goldman & Darius N. Lakdawalla, 2021. "Predicting quantity and quality of life with the Future Elderly Model," Health Economics, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., vol. 30(S1), pages 52-79, November.
    3. Imtiaz Bhatti & Marvin Phaup, 2015. "Budgeting for Fiscal Uncertainty and Bias: A Federal Process Proposal," Public Budgeting & Finance, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 35(2), pages 89-105, June.
    4. Kazumasa Oguro, 2014. "Challenges confronting Abenomics and Japanese public finance ?Fiscal consolidation must start by squarely facing reality?," Public Policy Review, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance Japan, vol. 10(2), pages 301-318, August.
    5. Robert Garnett & Kimmarie Mcgoldrick, 2014. "A 'Big Think' Approach to Government Debt: Promoting Significant Learning in Introductory Macroeconomics," Review of Political Economy, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 26(4), pages 628-647, October.
    6. Thomas Url & Rob J Hyndman & Alexander Dokumentov, 2016. "Long-term forecasts of age-specific participation rates with functional data models," Monash Econometrics and Business Statistics Working Papers 3/16, Monash University, Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics.
    7. Jason L. Saving & Alan D. Viard, 2015. "Are income taxes destined to rise? the fiscal imbalance and future tax policy," Working Papers 1502, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
    8. Michael Clemens, 2021. "The Fiscal Effect of Immigration: Reducing Bias in Influential Estimates," CESifo Working Paper Series 9464, CESifo.
    9. Òscar Jordà & Chitra Marti & Fernanda Nechio & Eric Tallman, 2019. "Inflation: Stress-Testing the Phillips Curve," FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
    10. Alan J Auerbach, 2016. "Long-Term Fiscal Sustainability in Advanced Economies," Asia and the Pacific Policy Studies, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 3(2), pages 142-154, May.
    11. Holston, Kathryn & Laubach, Thomas & Williams, John C., 2017. "Measuring the natural rate of interest: International trends and determinants," Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol. 108(S1), pages 59-75.
    12. Thomas Laubach & John C. Williams, 2015. "Measuring the natural rate of interest redux," Working Paper Series 2015-16, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
    13. Thomas Url & Rob J. Hyndman & Alexander Dokumentov, 2016. "Long-term Forecasts of Age-specific Labour Market Participation Rates with Functional Data Models," WIFO Working Papers 510, WIFO.
    14. Canyon Bosler & Mary C. Daly & John G. Fernald & Bart Hobijn, 2017. "The Outlook for US Labor-Quality Growth," NBER Chapters, in: Education, Skills, and Technical Change: Implications for Future US GDP Growth, pages 61-110, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    15. William N. Butos, 2015. "The Bernanke Fed and "Credit Easing" Policies, 2008-2014," Journal of Private Enterprise, The Association of Private Enterprise Education, vol. 30(Winter 20), pages 1-15.
    16. D. Tverdokhlibova, 2018. "Theory and practice of the use of fiscal sustainability indicators," Economy and Forecasting, Valeriy Heyets, issue 3, pages 7-47.
    17. Yuki Demizu & Daizo Kojima & Takahide Koike, 2018. "What Causes Errors in Projections of Medical and Long-term Care Expenses?," Public Policy Review, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance Japan, vol. 14(4), pages 563-584, July.

    More about this item

    JEL classification:

    • H2 - Public Economics - - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ucp:tpolec:doi:10.1086/683363. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Journals Division (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/TPE .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.