IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/pubcho/v42y1984i1p55-71.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

The social choice of alternative corrective devices

Author

Listed:
  • Stuart Mestelman

Abstract

The social preference of corrective taxation to corrective subsidy or to a policy of no action at all is examined within the context of a simple general general equilibrium framework in which an external production diseconomy exists. Equilibrium positions are obtained for a number of different parameter sets and resource endowments. For each equilibrium position, different mechanisms are introduced as procedures for distributing revenues accruing to a central authority which administers the corrective tax, or for collecting revenues to finance a subsidy programme. The only income redistribution which occurs in this economy is through these distribution mechanisms. Any change in policy regarding the correction of allocation inefficiencies resulting from the existence of externalities in the economy will be reflected in changes in prices (of both final goods and resources) and the resulting income redistribution necessitated by the need for revenues by the central authority or the need to reduce tax collections from individuals (if a corrective tax yields revenues from an industry) to maintain a balanced budget constraint. In an economy in which no government goods are produced, a tax reduction implies transfers to individuals. Within this framework, the following results emerge. 1. If the distribution mechanism is regressive, proportional or progressive, the corrective tax will always be preferred to the corrective subsidy as a method for internalizing external costs. Only under extreme progressivity does this support become unanimous. In all other situations only the agents controlling the one particular resource which identifies the firm will oppose the choice of the tax. 2. The status quo equilibrium will also be preferred to the equilibrium resulting from the use of a corrective subsidy. Again this result occurs consistently, and with the same coalition of agents supporting the status quo as supported the corrective tax. 3. Only under the proportional mechanism is the corrective tax preferred consistently to a ‘do nothing’ policy. If the distribution mechanism is progressive or regressive, there exist situations in which the status quo equilibrium state will be preferred by a majority of individuals to the state resulting after corrective action is taken, and resources are efficiently allocated. As progression increases, the likelihood of the corrective tax finding support from a majority of the agents in this economy tends to fall. 4. While majorities may exist, they appear to be tenuous, at best, in many situations. The difference between utility levels is at times very small, and with the introduction of transaction costs associated with casting a vote, some individuals may find it less costly to abstain from voting. In cases such as these, a majority of those voting may oppose an alternative which would have been supported had transaction costs not been introduced. There is also the problem of whether or not individuals actually perceive small differences in utility from state to state. However, since the model has demand functions based upon individuals who maximize a particular utility function, it would be inconsistent to assume that as consumers they are aware of their utility when choosing between different commodity bundles, but when comparing alternate states, they suddenly have a perception problem. The assumption of threshold perceptions for utility differences would require the development of an entirely different demand function. This extension does not appear to be as profitable as the introduction of transaction costs. 5. The distribution mechanism and the progressivity of the mechanism are exogenously determined. The convention that voters choose from among competing corrective devices but do not choose the degree of progression or the specific form of the mechanism could be relaxed. The easiest extension of this work can include both the choice of the progressivity of the distribution mechanism and the choice of the corrective device. 6. A further extension of this work could include a role for the central authority within the equilibrium framework as a user of resources. Not only may voting carry a cost, but the implementation and monitoring of corrective policies require resources. This results in incentives in conflicting directions. The costs involved in administering a programme reduce the potential gains to consumers, while the expansion of an industry (the central authority) provides benefits to others (bureaucrats). To the extent that the resources used in the production of corrective policies gain, particular groups may find income increases which offset price increases and make a costly corrective scheme more desirable than no action at all. 7. Another valuable extension of this work would be to generalize the production and utility functions to examine the implications of the model with variable elasticities of substitution between the inputs used in the two industries. A further change within this framework would be to introduce an externality which results in increasing marginal damages, rather than the decreasing marginal damages exhibited in this model. The earlier conjecture in Mestelman (1982b), suggesting that corrective subsidies may be preferred to corrective taxes under some distribution mechanisms, has not been demonstrated with this model of an economy. However, the work of Buchanan and Tullock (1975) which shows that efficiency need not imply social preference, and that the effect of any policy on the agents who make up the society must be identified if the failure of positive prescriptions is to be understood, is confirmed by this work, within a general equilibrium framework. The results of the experiments reported here suggest that for policy changes which require that resources be either collected from consumers or returned to consumers in a fashion that does not distort relative prices (in this model the leisure-labour decision is not considered), a distribution mechanism which is progressive may impede the adoption of policies directed at correcting allocation inefficiencies attributed to externalities. The model from which these results follow is certainly not an accurate representation of any actual economy, yet the results do point to the relevance of the financing of government regulatory policies. The distribution of income, and the effect on this distribution by government policies not necessarily intended to redistribute income, may significantly effect the success of those policies. Copyright Martinus Nijhoff Publishers 1984

Suggested Citation

  • Stuart Mestelman, 1984. "The social choice of alternative corrective devices," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 42(1), pages 55-71, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:42:y:1984:i:1:p:55-71
    DOI: 10.1007/BF00124599
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/BF00124599
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/BF00124599?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Buchanan, James M & Tullock, Gordon, 1975. "Polluters' Profits and Political Response: Direct Controls Versus Taxes," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 65(1), pages 139-147, March.
    2. Dennis W. Carlton & Glenn C. Loury, 1980. "The Limitations of Pigouvian Taxes as a Long-Run Remedy for Externalities," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 95(3), pages 559-566.
    3. Mestelman, Stuart, 1982. "Production externalities and corrective subsidies: A general equilibrium analysis," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Elsevier, vol. 9(2), pages 186-193, June.
    4. Cordes, Joseph J, 1980. "The Relative Efficiency of Taxes and Standards," Public Finance = Finances publiques, , vol. 35(3), pages 339-343.
    5. Gene Mumy, 1980. "Long-run efficiency and property rights sharing for pollution control," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 35(1), pages 59-74, January.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Per Fredriksson, 2001. "How Pollution Taxes may Increase Pollution and Reduce Net Revenues," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 107(1), pages 65-85, April.
    2. Yong Liu & Fei Li & Yunpeng Su, 2019. "Critical Factors Influencing the Evolution of Companies’ Environmental Behavior: An Agent-Based Computational Economic Approach," SAGE Open, , vol. 9(1), pages 21582440198, February.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. John Pezzey, 2003. "Emission Taxes and Tradeable Permits A Comparison of Views on Long-Run Efficiency," Environmental & Resource Economics, Springer;European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, vol. 26(2), pages 329-342, October.
    2. Marcus Berliant & Shin-Kun Peng & Ping Wang, 2014. "Taxing pollution: agglomeration and welfare consequences," Economic Theory, Springer;Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory (SAET), vol. 55(3), pages 665-704, April.
    3. Pezzey, John C.V. & Jotzo, Frank, 2010. "Tax-Versus-Trading and Free Emission Shares as Issues for Climate Policy Design," Research Reports 95049, Australian National University, Environmental Economics Research Hub.
    4. Cropper, Maureen L & Oates, Wallace E, 1992. "Environmental Economics: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 30(2), pages 675-740, June.
    5. Ko, Il-Dong, 1988. "Issues in the control of stock externality problems with inflexible policy measures," ISU General Staff Papers 198801010800009859, Iowa State University, Department of Economics.
    6. Revesz, Richard & Stavins, Robert, 2004. "Environmental Law and Policy," Working Paper Series rwp04-023, Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government.
    7. Wallace E. Oates, 1990. "Economics, Economists, and Environmental Policy," Eastern Economic Journal, Eastern Economic Association, vol. 16(4), pages 289-296, Oct-Dec.
    8. Don Fullerton & Gilbert E. Metcalf, 2002. "Environmental Controls, Scarcity Rents, and Pre-existing Distortions," Chapters, in: Lawrence H. Goulder (ed.), Environmental Policy Making in Economies with Prior Tax Distortions, chapter 26, pages 504-522, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    9. Bommer, Rolf, 1995. "Environmental policy and industrial competitiveness: The pollution haven hypothesis reconsidered," Discussion Papers, Series II 262, University of Konstanz, Collaborative Research Centre (SFB) 178 "Internationalization of the Economy".
    10. Andr, Francisco J. & Gonzlez, Paula & Porteiro, Nicols, 2009. "Strategic quality competition and the Porter Hypothesis," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Elsevier, vol. 57(2), pages 182-194, March.
    11. Johannes Urpelainen, 2012. "How do electoral competition and special interests shape the stringency of renewable energy standards?," Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, Springer;Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies - SEEPS, vol. 14(1), pages 23-34, January.
    12. Robert A. Leone & John E. Jackson, 1981. "The Political Economy of Federal Regulatory Activity: The Case of Water-Pollution Controls," NBER Chapters, in: Studies in Public Regulation, pages 231-276, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    13. Heider, Florian & Inderst, Roman, 2021. "A Corporate Finance Perspective on Environmental Policy," EconStor Preprints 253669, ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics.
    14. Sturm, Daniel & Ulph, Alistair, 2002. "Environment, trade, political economy and imperfect information: a survey," Discussion Paper Series In Economics And Econometrics 0204, Economics Division, School of Social Sciences, University of Southampton.
    15. Richard Schmalensee & Robert N. Stavins, 2019. "Policy Evolution under the Clean Air Act," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 33(4), pages 27-50, Fall.
    16. Helfand, Gloria E, 1991. "Standards versus Standards: The Effects of Different Pollution Restrictions," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 81(3), pages 622-634, June.
    17. Stephen F. Hamilton, 1998. "Taxation, Fines, and Producer Liability Rules: Efficiency and Market Structure Implications," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 65(1), pages 140-150, July.
    18. Stavins, Robert, 2004. "Environmental Economics," RFF Working Paper Series dp-04-54, Resources for the Future.
    19. Dieter Schmidtchen & Jenny Helstroffer & Christian Koboldt, 2021. "Regulatory failure and the polluter pays principle: why regulatory impact assessment dominates the polluter pays principle," Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, Springer;Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies - SEEPS, vol. 23(1), pages 109-144, January.
    20. Robert W. Hahn & Robert N. Stavins, 2011. "The Effect of Allowance Allocations on Cap-and-Trade System Performance," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 54(S4), pages 267-294.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:42:y:1984:i:1:p:55-71. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.