IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/vuw/vuwcsr/19021.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

The Optimal Network Contract Under Partial Bypass in Oligopolistic Network Industries

Author

Listed:
  • Evans, Lewis
  • Burnell, Stephen
  • Yao, Shuntian

Abstract

The rapid widespread technological change and concomitant deregulation of network industries has engendered a burgeoning demand for connection between technologically similar as well as technologically dissimilar networks. The processes by which interconnection contracts are reached and the nature of these contracts is important for the performance of these industries. The basis for public policy concern about these contracts stems from the perception that there remain natural monopoly elements in networks. Wherethese elements are absent or equivalently if networks are open to economic bypass interconnection contracts will generally not pose special competition concerns. The purpose of this paper is to examine the effect of credible potential bypass of a network on the economic efficiency of a privately chosen network contract. There is no regulation excepting the requirement that there must be no non-price discrimination against a firm that wishes to utilise the network.The set up is one in which there are two downstream retail firms that require a network to do business. They supply different but possibly very similar services and they compete as a duopoly for retail customers. They each face the same contract for the use of the network. There is a vertically integrated firm (the incumbent) that owns the network and one retail firm. Two organisational structures are considered. In one the vertically integrated firm is a conglomerate that chooses the network contract and its retail firm's output subject only to the reaction of the other retail firm. The second is a divisional organisational structure where the incumbent's retail firm takes the network contract as given and acts independently to maximise profits subject to interaction with the other retail firm. In the divisional structure the network contract is designed to maximise the profits of the total firm but subject to divisional autonomy. The divisional structure yields relatively more efficient contracts than does the conglomerate but total incumbent profits are lower. As a practical matter this represents a factor to be considered in choosing an organisational structure because there canbe organisational performance gains in decentralised structures.The second retail firm may build its own network to bypass the incumbent's network. There is no regulatory intervention and because of the threat of bypass the vertically integrated firm does not price the other firm off the network. The vertically integrated firm has the inherent natural monopoly characteristic of taking leadership in the design of its two-part tariffcontract for the use of its network. It therefore designs the network contract taking cognisance of the ability of the second retail firm to construct a bypass network and its strategic output reaction to actions of the incumbent.The results indicate that when the full network has to be bypassed if at all the vertically integrated firm has very considerable latitude to raise the variable component of the network charge to restrict the other retail firm's output. This inefficient situation is tantamount to bypass not being possible.The position is different when the second retail firm can partially bypass the incumbent's network and use a combination of its own and the incumbent's network to service customers. Assuming that if the second retail firm did partially bypass it would do so by bypassing targeted network segments that are relatively densely populated by potential subscribers (e.g. the central business district) partial bypass is such a threat to the incumbent that it designs a much more efficient contract. The vertically integrated firm designs a contract that raises the variable component of the network contract as much as possible to reduce the outside firm's output while ensuring that the outside retail firm does not bypass much of the network. This threat of bypass forces in the range of examples described in the paper a relatively efficientoutcome and a contract that approximates the incumbent's network cost function.Because the network contracts are relatively economically efficient the profit performance of the divisional and conglomerate structures are so similar that a choice between them could be made on grounds of organisational performance. This is not considered in the paper.Although the paper's assumption that there is one contract for all segments of the network is restrictive the paper does illustrate the strong competitive influence of potential bypass on an unregulated firm's choice of a network contract.

Suggested Citation

  • Evans, Lewis & Burnell, Stephen & Yao, Shuntian, 1999. "The Optimal Network Contract Under Partial Bypass in Oligopolistic Network Industries," Working Paper Series 19021, Victoria University of Wellington, The New Zealand Institute for the Study of Competition and Regulation.
  • Handle: RePEc:vuw:vuwcsr:19021
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://ir.wgtn.ac.nz/handle/123456789/19021
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean, 1994. "Access pricing and competition," European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 38(9), pages 1673-1710, December.
    2. Perry, Martin K., 1989. "Vertical integration: Determinants and effects," Handbook of Industrial Organization, in: R. Schmalensee & R. Willig (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, edition 1, volume 1, chapter 4, pages 183-255, Elsevier.
    3. Jean-Jacques Laffont & Jean Tirole, 1993. "A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation," MIT Press Books, The MIT Press, edition 1, volume 1, number 0262121743, December.
    4. Waterson, Michael, 1987. "Recent Developments in the Theory of Natural Monopoly," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 1(1), pages 59-80.
    5. Dixit, Avinash, 1982. "Recent Developments in Oligopoly Theory," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 72(2), pages 12-17, May.
    6. Weingast, Barry R & Moran, Mark J, 1983. "Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 91(5), pages 765-800, October.
    7. Baumol, William J & Bailey, Elizabeth E & Willig, Robert D, 1977. "Weak Invisible Hand Theorems on the Sustainability of Multiproduct Natural Monopoly," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 67(3), pages 350-365, June.
    8. Michael D. Whinston & Scott C. Collins, 1992. "Entry and Competitive Structure in Deregulated Airline Markets: An Event Study Analysis of People Express," RAND Journal of Economics, The RAND Corporation, vol. 23(4), pages 445-462, Winter.
    9. Brock, William A, 1983. "Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure: A Review Article," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 91(6), pages 1055-1066, December.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. repec:vuw:vuwscr:19021 is not listed on IDEAS
    2. Evans, Lewis & Burnell, Stephen & Yao, Shuntian, 1999. "The Optimal Network Contract Under Partial Bypass in Oligopolistic Network Industries," Working Paper Series 3922, Victoria University of Wellington, The New Zealand Institute for the Study of Competition and Regulation.
    3. Stephen P. King, 1997. "National Competition Policy," The Economic Record, The Economic Society of Australia, vol. 73(222), pages 270-284, September.
    4. Armstrong, Mark & Sappington, David E.M., 2007. "Recent Developments in the Theory of Regulation," Handbook of Industrial Organization, in: Mark Armstrong & Robert Porter (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, edition 1, volume 3, chapter 27, pages 1557-1700, Elsevier.
    5. Lehr, William & Sicker, Douglas, 2017. "Communications Act 2021," 28th European Regional ITS Conference, Passau 2017 169478, International Telecommunications Society (ITS).
    6. Bickenbach, Frank, 2000. "Regulation of Europe's network industries: the perspective of the new economic theory of federalism," Kiel Working Papers 977, Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW Kiel).
    7. Vogelsang, Ingo, 2000. "Regulation of Access to the Telecommunications Network of New Zealand: A Review of the Literature," Working Paper Series 3931, Victoria University of Wellington, The New Zealand Institute for the Study of Competition and Regulation.
    8. Lars Kumkar, 2003. "Regulatory Choices and Commitment: Challenges for Electricity Market Regulation in Kosovo," Post-Communist Economies, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 15(1), pages 91-115.
    9. Weisman, Dennis L., 2001. "Access pricing and exclusionary behavior," Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 72(1), pages 121-126, July.
    10. Cyril Benoît, 2021. "Politicians, regulators, and regulatory governance: The neglected sides of the story," Regulation & Governance, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 15(S1), pages 8-22, November.
    11. Herguera, Iñigo & Martinelli, César, 1995. "Regulación de precios de interconexion," DE - Documentos de Trabajo. Economía. DE 10737, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Departamento de Economía.
    12. Moszoro, Marian W. & Spiller, Pablo T., 2014. "Third-Party Opportunism and the Theory of Public Contracts: Operationalization and Applications," MPRA Paper 101592, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    13. David Besanko & Shana Cui, 2019. "Regulated versus negotiated access pricing in vertically separated railway systems," Journal of Regulatory Economics, Springer, vol. 55(1), pages 1-32, February.
    14. Newbery, David & Affuso, Luisa, 2000. "Investment, Reprocurement and Franchise Contract Length in the British Railway Industry," CEPR Discussion Papers 2619, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    15. Joao Vareda, 2007. "Access regulation under asymmetric information about demand," Nova SBE Working Paper Series wp525, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, Nova School of Business and Economics.
    16. P. Hägg, 1997. "Theories on the Economics of Regulation: A Survey of the Literature from a European Perspective," European Journal of Law and Economics, Springer, vol. 4(4), pages 337-370, December.
    17. Mika Kato, 2016. "Jean Tirole, Nobel Prize Winner," Review of Political Economy, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 28(1), pages 23-44, January.
    18. Drew Fudenberg, 2015. "Tirole's Industrial Regulation and Organization Legacy in Economics," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 117(3), pages 771-800, July.
    19. Spencer, Barbara J & Qiu, Larry D, 2001. "Keiretsu and Relationship-Specific Investment: A Barrier to Trade?," International Economic Review, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania and Osaka University Institute of Social and Economic Research Association, vol. 42(4), pages 871-901, November.
    20. Miltiadis Makris, 2006. "Political authority, expertise and government bureaucracies," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 127(3), pages 267-284, June.
    21. Timo Goeschl & Johannes Jarke, 2013. "The warnings puzzle: an upstream explanation," Journal of Regulatory Economics, Springer, vol. 44(3), pages 339-360, December.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:vuw:vuwcsr:19021. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Library Technology Services (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/fcvuwnz.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.