IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/zbw/kondp2/317.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Trade and migration linkages: The case of NAFTA

Author

Listed:
  • Martin, Philip L.

Abstract

This paper reviews recent Mexico-US migration patterns and US reactions to Mexican immigration, explores why there may be a migration hump with two very different economies integrate, and discusses the policy options to deal with the extra migration associated with economic integration in North America. The major conclusion for policy makers is that a migration hump should be anticipated and dealt with; the major implication for economists is that the process of adjustment to new comparative statics equilibria can be important enough to affect economic integration itself. Migration represents one of the many asymmetries in Mexico-US relations- the United States accepts immigrants from many nations, but virtually all Mexican emigrants head for the United States. For most of the 20th Century, the US encouraged or tolerated a "go north for opportunity" mentality, especially in rural Mexico, so that, when Mexico experienced devaluations and economic shocks in the 1980s, many Mexicans "naturally" looked to the US as a safety valve. The economic integration symbolized by NAFTA was supposed to turn the "people relationship" between the US and Mexico into a "trade and investment relationship." US Presidents Bush and Clinton, and Mexican President Salinas, argued that economic integration was the best way to reduce emigration pressures in Mexico. In the words of Mexican President Salinas, "more jobs will mean higher wages in Mexico, and this in turn will mean fewer migrants to the United States and Canada. We want to export goods, not people." (quoted in Bush letter to Congress, May 1, 1991,17). The U.S. Commission for the Study of International Migration and Cooperative Economic Development, however, as well as most migration specialists, predicted that economic integration between the very different Mexican and the US economies would produce a migration hump-temporarily more migration, and then less, because "the economic development process itself tends in the short to medium term to stimulate migration." (Final Report, 1990, xvi). Economic integration and other policies that accelerate economic growth thus create "a very real short-term versus long-term dilemma" for the United States when dealing with unauthorized immigration, since the "the development Solution to unauthorized migration is measured in decades-even generations" (1990, xxxvi). NAFTA went into effect on January 1, 1994, a year that proved to be eventful in Mexico, with a Zapatista uprising, several political assassinations, and a peso devaluation. Legal immigration to the US, and apprehensions of unauthorized Mexicans, fell 10 to 20 percent in 1994, not as much as many expected. Some US politicians and immigration control advocates were able to use footage of "kamikaze" sprints by groups of unauthorized Mexicans through the US port of entry, as well as the lingering effects of recession, to re-elect California Governor Wilson and to approve Proposition 187, a State initiative that, if implemented, would make it more difficult for unauthorized aliens to obtain public services. The number of Mexican-born US residents appears to have increased sharply in the 1990s, supporting the proposition that migration hump is a feature of economic integration. There were 4.3 million legal and illegal Mexican-born residents enumerated in the 1990 Census, 6.3 million in the March 1994 CPS, and 6.7 million in the March 1995 CPS. Over 70 percent of the 1.1 million immigrants waiting to bring their spouses and children to the US are Mexicans and, by some estimates, most of them are already living in the US. Even more Mexicans are expected in the next five years. The number of people living in rural Mexico is likely to be halved from the current 24 to 27 million over the next 10 to 20 years, which means that 3 to 4 million rural households-which average 5 to 6 persons each- that now depend on farming must find nonfarm jobs within commuting distance of their current residences, migrate to Mexican cities for nonfarm jobs, or migrate to the US. Most migration specialists predict that, if Mexico grows at an average rate that is 2 to 3 percent faster than the US growth rate- something that Mexico has been unable to do in the 1990s- the economic gaps that motivate most legal and illegal Mexico to US migration will narrow, and Mexico-US migration will fall to "manageable" levels at about the time that new US immigration control efforts are put fully in place, or in 10 to 20 years. In other words, Mexico-US migration in the mid-1990s is believed to be near the peak of the "migration hump;" migration is expected to diminish after 2005.

Suggested Citation

  • Martin, Philip L., 1996. "Trade and migration linkages: The case of NAFTA," Discussion Papers, Series II 317, University of Konstanz, Collaborative Research Centre (SFB) 178 "Internationalization of the Economy".
  • Handle: RePEc:zbw:kondp2:317
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/101664/1/770481094.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Gary Clyde Hufbauer & Jeffrey J. Schott, 1992. "North American Free Trade: Issues and Recommendations," Peterson Institute Press: All Books, Peterson Institute for International Economics, number 71, January.
    2. Philip L. Martin, 1993. "Trade and Migration: NAFTA and Agriculture," Peterson Institute Press: All Books, Peterson Institute for International Economics, number pa38, January.
    3. Hinojosa-Ojeda, Raul & Robinson, Sherman, 1992. "Labor Issues in a North American Free Trade Area," CUDARE Working Papers 198601, University of California, Berkeley, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics.
    4. Wolfgang F. Stolper & Paul A. Samuelson, 1941. "Protection and Real Wages," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 9(1), pages 58-73.
    5. Abowd, John M. & Freeman, Richard B. (ed.), 1991. "Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market," National Bureau of Economic Research Books, University of Chicago Press, edition 1, number 9780226000954, December.
    6. John M. Abowd & Richard B. Freeman, 1991. "Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market," NBER Books, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, number abow91-1, March.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Philip Martin, 2003. "Economic Integration and Migration: The Mexico-US Case," WIDER Working Paper Series DP2003-35, World Institute for Development Economic Research (UNU-WIDER).
    2. Tschopp, Jeanne, 2015. "The Wage Response to Shocks: The Role of Inter-Occupational Labour Adjustment," Labour Economics, Elsevier, vol. 37(C), pages 28-37.
    3. Lukas Mohler & Rolf Weder & Simone Wyss, 2018. "International trade and unemployment: towards an investigation of the Swiss case," Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, Springer;Swiss Society of Economics and Statistics, vol. 154(1), pages 1-12, December.
    4. Greenwood, Michael J. & Hunt, Gary L. & Kohli, Ulrich, 1997. "The factor-market consequences of unskilled immigration to the United States," Labour Economics, Elsevier, vol. 4(1), pages 1-28, March.
    5. John T. Addison & Douglas A. Fox & Christopher J. Ruhm, 2000. "Technology, Trade Sensitivity, and Labor Displacement," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 66(3), pages 682-699, January.
    6. Robert Z. Lawrence, 1994. "Trade, Multinationals, & Labor," NBER Working Papers 4836, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    7. Robert Z. Lawrence & Matthew J. Slaughter, 1993. "International Trade and American Wages in the 1980s: Giant Sucking Sound or Small Hiccup?," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, The Brookings Institution, vol. 24(2 Microec), pages 161-226.
    8. Ottaviano, Gianmarco & Peri, Giovanni, 2008. "Immigration and National Wages: Clarifying the Theory and the Empirics," CEPR Discussion Papers 6916, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    9. Peter Huber & Helmut Hofer, 2001. "Teilprojekt 9: Auswirkungen der EU-Erweiterung auf den österreichischen Arbeitsmarkt," WIFO Studies, WIFO, number 19839, February.
    10. Gianmarco I. P. Ottaviano & Giovanni Peri, 2021. "Rethinking The Effect Of Immigration On Wages," World Scientific Book Chapters, in: Firms and Workers in a Globalized World Larger Markets, Tougher Competition, chapter 9, pages 245-290, World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd..
    11. Kristiina Huttunen & Jarle Møen & Kjell G. Salvanes, 2018. "Job Loss and Regional Mobility," Journal of Labor Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 36(2), pages 479-509.
    12. Morrison Paul, Catherine J. & Siegel, Donald, 1997. "Automation Or Openness?: Technology And Trade Impacts On Costs And Labor Composition In The Food System," Strategy and Policy in the Food System: Emerging Issues, June 20-21, 1996, Washington, D.C. 25940, Regional Research Project NE-165 Private Strategies, Public Policies, and Food System Performance.
    13. Rashid, Saman, 2004. "Immigrant Earnings, Assimilation and Heterogeneity," Umeå Economic Studies 622, Umeå University, Department of Economics.
    14. Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano & Giovanni Peri, 2005. "Rethinking the Gains from Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the U.S," NBER Working Papers 11672, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    15. Michael A. Clemens & Claudio Montenegro & Lant Pritchett, 2016. "Bounding the Price Equivalent of Migration Barriers," CID Working Papers 316, Center for International Development at Harvard University.
    16. Patacchini, Eleonora & Zenou, Yves, 2012. "Ethnic networks and employment outcomes," Regional Science and Urban Economics, Elsevier, vol. 42(6), pages 938-949.
    17. Gordon H. Hanson & Antonio Spilimbergo, 2001. "Political economy, sectoral shocks, and border enforcement," Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 34(3), pages 612-638, August.
    18. Tito Boeri & Marta De Philippis & Eleonora Patacchini & Michele Pellizzari, 2015. "Immigration, Housing Discrimination and Employment," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 125(586), pages 82-114, August.
    19. Ted Nabil ARANKI, 2001. "The Effect of Israeli Closure Policy on Wage Earnings in the West Bank and Gaza Strip," Middle East and North Africa 330400006, EcoMod.
    20. Steven J. Davis & Magnus Henrekson, 1997. "Industrial Policy, Employer Size, and Economic Performance in Sweden," NBER Chapters, in: The Welfare State in Transition: Reforming the Swedish Model, pages 353-398, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:zbw:kondp2:317. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/fwkonde.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.