IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/pubcho/v60y1989i2p155-175.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Plurality and runoff systems and numbers of candidates

Author

Listed:
  • Stephen Wright
  • William Riker

Abstract

Although political scientists have in the last few decades learned much about the abstract properties of multicandidate electoral systems, we have accumulated little theoretical knowledge on the ways in which strategic behavior of voters and candidates changes when we move from one voting system to another. This essay has illustrated how the relative desirability of voting systems can change when the number of candidates — usually considered fixed in such comparisons — is taken as endogenous to the voting system in force at the time. Our main conclusion is, therefore, that the method of voting must be understood in relation to the total electoral system. It is not enough to analyze properties of voting systems in the abstract, but also in terms of the interactions that voting systems have with political groups and the constitutional setting. A complete comparison should, consequently, consider also the way in which these systems tend to reduce or inflate the number of candidates. Indeed, the process by which actual candidacies are eliminated may be as important as the fact that the numbers are reduced. In a sense, both plurality and runoff reduce the relevant candidates in different ways: runoff through the mechanical elimination of all but the top two candidates (assuming no candidate receives a majority of the vote), and plurality, through the pre-election negotiations and calculations that tend to discourage candidates who fear they may not come in first. One particularly difficult problem is the possibility that plurality, in the process of discouraging candidates who do not expect to come in first, may also discourage potential Condorcet winners from running. Under the runoff system a Condorcet candidate, even though squeezed on both left and right, may choose to run, hoping for a second place finish that may translate to a majority at the second election. Likewise, a dark horse candidate, who is potentially a Condorcet winner given appropriate publicity following a second place finish initially, also has an incentive to run. In this second example, the identity of the Condorcet candidate is dynamic. By contrast, under plurality, such present or potential Condorcet candidates may fail to announce. These concerns seem to be echoed in the Blacks' (1987) study of the current southern experience with the runoff system, which, in the absence of strong party organizations, ‘provid[es] a mechanism for eliminating many weak frontrunners — candidates who might be able to win a small plurality of the vote in a crowded first primary field but who would likely be ineffective campaigners in the general election’ (Black and Black, 1986: 6). They also find that strong frontrunners in runoff gubernatorial primaries — candidates who win at least 40 percent of the initial primary vote and have at least a 5 percentage point lead over their closest rival — have not lost an election in the last two decades. Political novices or dark horses, meanwhile, who manage to qualify for the runoff against an incumbent, generally perform quite well. Of course, whether these candidates are Condorcet winners and whether, more generally, the runoff system does in fact favor ‘potential’ Condorcet candidates is not known. In fact, there is little direct empirical evidence on the existence or emergence of Condorcet winners among given candidate fields competing under either the runoff or plurality system. And one important investigation for future research is, for example, to discover how and why a Condorcet winner in a 14-candidate field becomes non-Condorcet when there are 8–13 candidates, and then Condorcet again when there are 3–7 candidates. A less puzzling problem concerns the reluctance of southern Democrats to abandon the runoff system, which continues to serve the electoral interests of that party (Stanley, 1985). Likewise, the vast majority of states continue to use the plurality method, perhaps because it maintains a political status quo, or perhaps because politicians recognize, if only dimly, the attractive features of simple majority decision promoted by the use of this rule. Similarly, that the dynamic movement toward only a few candidates might still involve certain unfairness was probably perceived by those adopting the runoff primary in the South. Thus, while the historical origins of the runoff system have not been thoroughly investigated, it seems likely that with the disappearance of the two-party system (and the accompanying weakening of the southern Democratic party organization) in the 1890s, southern Democrats wished to avoid the bruising intra-party contests that might have resulted under plurality rule. Alternatively, where the two-party system still existed, the runoff provided a means to incorporate the many factions of the Democratic party with less risk that these groups might ‘bolt’ that party (Kousser, 1984). Then, as Key (1949) suggests, they might simply have hoped — in the event that many factions or candidates were not initially deterred from entering primary races — to avoid nominating ‘minority’ candidates. Unfortunately, while we know little on the historical origins of the runoff primary, we know even less about the dynamics of the operation of electoral systems such as plurality and runoff, in terms of their effects on the status of potential (as well as eventual) Condorcet candidates. The tentative conclusion from this essay thus reaffirms that of Arrow (1951), as elaborated elsewhere (Riker, 1982b): speaking descriptively, voting systems operate in ways that are not fully understood; speaking normatively, all voting systems are unfair in certain ways. Still, we have learned that the plurality system is much more efficient in selecting Condorcet winners than previous research suggests and is in fact more efficient than the runoff system in this regard. Copyright Kluwer Academic Publishers 1989

Suggested Citation

  • Stephen Wright & William Riker, 1989. "Plurality and runoff systems and numbers of candidates," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 60(2), pages 155-175, February.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:60:y:1989:i:2:p:155-175
    DOI: 10.1007/BF00149243
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/BF00149243
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/BF00149243?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Stanley, Harold W. & Bianco, William T. & Niemi, Richard G., 1986. "Partisanship and Group Support Over Time: A Multivariate Analysis," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 80(3), pages 969-976, September.
    2. Greenberg, Joseph & Shepsle, Kenneth, 1987. "The Effect of Electoral Rewards in Multiparty Competition with Entry," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 81(2), pages 525-537, June.
    3. Thomas R. Palfrey, 1984. "Spatial Equilibrium with Entry," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 51(1), pages 139-156.
    4. Anthony Downs, 1957. "An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 65(2), pages 135-135.
    5. Samuel Merrill, 1985. "A statistical model for Condorcet efficiency based on simulation under spatial model assumptions," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 47(2), pages 389-403, January.
    6. Riker, William H., 1982. "The Two-party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 76(4), pages 753-766, December.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Torres, Javier & Díaz, Guillermo, 2019. "Effects of runoff voting rules on number of parties and candidates' political experience: Evidence from a law change in Peru," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 59(C), pages 97-107.
    2. Brusco, Sandro & Dziubiński, Marcin & Roy, Jaideep, 2012. "The Hotelling–Downs model with runoff voting," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 74(2), pages 447-469.
    3. Bordignon, Massimo & Nannicini, Tommaso & Tabellini, Guido, 2017. "Single round vs. runoff elections under plurality rule: A theoretical analysis," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 49(C), pages 123-133.
    4. Laurent Bouton & Jorge Gallego & Aniol Llorente-Saguer & Rebecca Morton, 2022. "Run-off Elections in the Laboratory," The Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 132(641), pages 106-146.
    5. Peter Kurrild-Klitgaard, 2014. "Empirical social choice: an introduction," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 158(3), pages 297-310, March.
    6. Massimo Bordignon & Guido Tabellini, 2009. "Moderating Political Extremism: Single Round vs Runoff Elections under Plurality Rule," DISCE - Quaderni dell'Istituto di Economia e Finanza ief0087, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Dipartimenti e Istituti di Scienze Economiche (DISCE).
    7. Arvate, Paulo Roberto, 2013. "Electoral Competition and Local Government Responsiveness in Brazil," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 43(C), pages 67-83.
    8. Sandro Brusco & Jaideep Roy, 2011. "Aggregate uncertainty in the citizen candidate model yields extremist parties," Social Choice and Welfare, Springer;The Society for Social Choice and Welfare, vol. 36(1), pages 83-104, January.
    9. Laurent Bouton, 2013. "A Theory of Strategic Voting in Runoff Elections," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 103(4), pages 1248-1288, June.
    10. César Martinelli, 2002. "Simple plurality versus plurality runoff with privately informed voters," Social Choice and Welfare, Springer;The Society for Social Choice and Welfare, vol. 19(4), pages 901-919.
    11. Guido De Blasio & Guglielmo Barone, 2011. "Local electoral rules and political participation," ERSA conference papers ersa11p418, European Regional Science Association.
    12. Barone, Guglielmo & de Blasio, Guido, 2013. "Electoral rules and voter turnout," International Review of Law and Economics, Elsevier, vol. 36(C), pages 25-35.
    13. Peter Kurrild-Klitgaard, 2014. "Picking a loser? A social choice perspective on the Danish government formation of 1975," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 158(3), pages 483-497, March.
    14. Mogens K. Justesen, 2007. "The Social Choice of EU Treaties," European Union Politics, , vol. 8(4), pages 537-553, December.
    15. Jeffrey O’Neill, 2007. "Choosing a runoff election threshold," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 131(3), pages 351-364, June.
    16. Martin J. Osborne & Al Slivinski, 1996. "A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 111(1), pages 65-96.
    17. Arnaud Dellis, 2013. "The two-party system under alternative voting procedures," Social Choice and Welfare, Springer;The Society for Social Choice and Welfare, vol. 40(1), pages 263-284, January.
    18. Lee, Sang-Gun & Chae, Seung Hoon & Cho, Kyung Min, 2013. "Drivers and inhibitors of SaaS adoption in Korea," International Journal of Information Management, Elsevier, vol. 33(3), pages 429-440.
    19. Mvukiyehe, Eric & Samii, Cyrus, 2017. "Promoting Democracy in Fragile States: Field Experimental Evidence from Liberia," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 95(C), pages 254-267.
    20. Buisseret, Peter, 2017. "Electoral competition with entry under non-majoritarian run-off rules," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 104(C), pages 494-506.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Arturas Rozenas, 2011. "Constituency size and stability of two-party systems," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 23(3), pages 344-358, July.
    2. Alexander Shapoval & Shlomo Weber & Alexei Zakharov, 2019. "Valence influence in electoral competition with rank objectives," International Journal of Game Theory, Springer;Game Theory Society, vol. 48(3), pages 713-753, September.
    3. Tsakas, Nikolas & Xefteris, Dimitrios, 2018. "Electoral competition with third party entry in the lab," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Elsevier, vol. 148(C), pages 121-134.
    4. Stanley Winer & Lawrence Kenny & Bernard Grofman, 2014. "Explaining variation in the competitiveness of U.S. Senate elections, 1922–2004," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 161(3), pages 471-497, December.
    5. Micael Castanheira, 2003. "Why Vote For Losers?," Journal of the European Economic Association, MIT Press, vol. 1(5), pages 1207-1238, September.
    6. Brusco, Sandro & Roy, Jaideep, 2016. "Cycles in public opinion and the dynamics of stable party systems," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 100(C), pages 413-430.
    7. Alastair Smith & Bruce Bueno de Mesquita & Tom LaGatta, 2017. "Group incentives and rational voting1," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 29(2), pages 299-326, April.
    8. Kei Kawai & Yasutora Watanabe, 2013. "Inferring Strategic Voting," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 103(2), pages 624-662, April.
    9. JuanD. Carrillo & Micael Castanheira, 2008. "Information and Strategic Political Polarisation," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 118(530), pages 845-874, July.
    10. Martínez-Mora, Francisco & Puy, M. Socorro, 2014. "The determinants and electoral consequences of asymmetric preferences," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 33(C), pages 85-97.
    11. Maria Gallego & Norman Schofield & Kevin McAlister & Jee Jeon, 2014. "The variable choice set logit model applied to the 2004 Canadian election," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 158(3), pages 427-463, March.
    12. Tanner, Thomas Cole, 1994. "The spatial theory of elections: an analysis of voters' predictive dimensions and recovery of the underlying issue space," ISU General Staff Papers 1994010108000018174, Iowa State University, Department of Economics.
    13. Stefan Krasa & Mattias Polborn, 2014. "Policy Divergence and Voter Polarization in a Structural Model of Elections," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 57(1), pages 31-76.
    14. Rusinowska, Agnieszka & Taalaibekova, Akylai, 2019. "Opinion formation and targeting when persuaders have extreme and centrist opinions," Journal of Mathematical Economics, Elsevier, vol. 84(C), pages 9-27.
    15. Iaryczower, Matias & Mattozzi, Andrea, 2008. "Ideology and competence in alternative electoral systems," Working Papers 1285, California Institute of Technology, Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences.
    16. Groseclose, Timothy J. & McCarty, Nolan, 1999. "The Politics of Blame: Bargaining before an Audience," Research Papers 1617, Stanford University, Graduate School of Business.
    17. Damien Bol & Arnaud Dellis & Mandar Oak, 2016. "Comparison of Voting Procedures Using Models of Electoral Competition with Endogenous Candidacy," Studies in Political Economy, in: Maria Gallego & Norman Schofield (ed.), The Political Economy of Social Choices, pages 21-54, Springer.
    18. Lindner, Axel, 2000. "Long-term appointment of central bankers: costs and benefits," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 16(4), pages 639-654, November.
    19. James Adams, 1998. "Partisan Voting and Multiparty Spatial Competition," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 10(1), pages 5-31, January.
    20. Martin J. Osborne & Al Slivinski, 1996. "A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 111(1), pages 65-96.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:60:y:1989:i:2:p:155-175. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.