IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ohe/monogr/000434.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Competition through Innovation, Innovation through Competition

Author

Listed:
  • Hannah Kettler

Abstract

Pharmaceutical companies report that in their dynamic, research and technology intensive industry, competitiveness is synonymous with innovativeness. That is, companies must invest in product research and development (R&D) to stay ahead. To afford this type of strategy, companies seek adequate reimbursement for their time, risk, and investments. Purchasers (governments, sickness funds, managed care organizations, insurance companies, patients) are concerned about getting value for their money and governments have the additional concern that their own country's industries compete effectively. In contrast to the industry's claims, a fear is intermittently voiced in policy debates that companies, in their pursuit of profits, are not investing in truly innovative medicines (Wastila et. al, 1989; Benzi, 1996). These industry critics 'contend that profit incentives motivate the multinational pharmaceutical industry to spend too much time, effort and money on 'me-too' research, as well as on research for line extensions of already marketed drugs' (Wastila et al., 1989, 106). These authors define a 'me-too' drug as a substance in the same chemical class and used for the same therapeutic indication as the innovator drug (first in class). The objective of this paper is to analyze the inference of these critics that the incremental improvements of so called 'me-toos' do not add economic and therapeutic value. 'Me-toos' are henceforth referred to as 'incremental innovations' to distinguish them from 'breakthrough innovations'. According to such criticisms, the prevalence of a 'me-too' R&D strategy would have three serious negative implications: 1. health care purchasers are paying for drugs adding little value; 'me-toos' are poor value for money; 2. companies are distracted from the real social task of serious innovation; a 'me-too' strategy will ultimately threaten these companies' long term competitiveness; 3. justly earned rents to the first entrant in a market are dissipated by the entry of many copies; excessive competition from 'me-toos' might discourage desirable investment in breakthrough innovation. To motivate companies to invest in higher quality R&D to produce innovative output, some European Parliament members have discussed the possibility of requiring products to meet an innovativeness standard. Repercussions for products failing to meet the standard might be, in the most extreme cases, the refusal of licensing approval by the European Medicines Evaluation Agency (EMEA), or the refusal of reimbursement or, more likely, a reimbursement only at a discount to the leading products in the class within the European Union (EU)3 (Benzi, 1996; Scientific and Technological Options Assessment for the European Parliament (STOA), 1993). It is hoped that such policies would discourage 'me-too' innovation, while encouraging breakthrough innovation. Such policies might, however, fail to achieve the intended end, and reduce the level of breakthrough innovation achieved by the pharmaceutical industry, as well as hitting socially useful incremental innovation - what Wells (1988) referred to as 'innovative chemical extensions'. Pharmaceutical companies argue that the process by which they develop breakthroughs and incremental innovations is one and the same; you cannot tell with any certainty when you are developing a product who will be first to market or who will produce the best product. The discovery and development processes are long and plagued with uncertainties. As a crude illustration of this, assuming the global industry average development time profile of 10-12 years, Diagram 2.1 shows that R&D investments of $12.7 billion worldwide in 1987 corresponded to 46 products obtaining market approval in 1997 (source: CMR International) . Given an average failure rate of 80%, this suggests that almost 200 compounds failed to make it through the clinical trial process. Companies who produce follower products do not necessarily start with a 'non-innovative' strategy. A threat of low reimbursements at the end of the process might therefore discourage, rather than encourage, investment which would have produced fundamental innovations. There are political and economic arguments against limiting the number of products approved in any one class. From a national competitiveness standpoint, European governments would not want to prevent their own companies from entering a market where the class leader is from outside the EU. There is also a strong case for incremental innovation. The full therapeutic value of a product is often not known until after it has been marketed to a large patient sample. The first product to market does not always turn out to be the best. Unexpected treatment or disease prevention benefits may emerge when use becomes widespread. This raises questions about the effectiveness of any external 'pre-market' evaluation of innovativeness to weed out 'useless' or 'low value' products. Incremental innovations may be of considerable value to payers. Some chemically similar follower products may add extra attributes that advance existing therapies. That is, they are 'innovative chemical extensions'. Multiple products in a therapeutic class also promote price competition, potentially bringing down the cost of health care. Policy makers might respond that in the case of imposing price discounts on follower drugs, they are simply formalizing pricing practices that frequently occur in the market anyway. There is evidence, discussed later in this paper, the producers of follower drugs do tend to introduce them at a price below the leading product. There is, however, a clear difference in the impact on incentives for companies, between a government ordained discount based on external assessments of product value and one that companies decided to offer in response to their perception of the market and the value of their product. Rather than impose additional regulatory hurdles at the licensing or reimbursement stage, therefore, the innovative value of pharmaceutical industry's output could instead be promoted by enhancing demand side pressures (informed payers and incentivised prescribers can get value for money) and by ensuring high rewards for breakthrough innovations. This debate raises important issues about the nature of pharmaceutical companies' R&D strategies and what motivates those investments, and about how and when to assess the value of pharmaceutical output. This report explores: 1. the pharmaceutical R&D process and the factors motivating investments in order to understand how companies may produce no or merely incremental innovations even while they strive for breakthrough innovations; 2. whether our understanding of the nature of an innovation can change across stages pre- and post-market launch; 3. the potential therapeutic and economic benefits which need to be set against the apparent redundancy of having multiple products m any one therapeutic class; and 4. whether ex-ante definitions of innovation can be made and are useful for public policy making. Section 3 presents the range of different definitions and indicators used by various authors and agencies in their attempts to measure pharmaceutical innovation. It is evidently difficult to produce an objective measure. How innovation is defined and measured depends on what the analyst wants to show. In Section 4 the pharmaceutical R&D process and the factors motivating investments in innovation are explored. Given the time and uncertainty involved in developing a new drug, successful innovation cannot be guaranteed but there are identifiable factors - some endogenous to firm strategy and some exogenous - that set the successful companies apart from the rest. Using information about the decision making process and the factors which encourage innovation, the possible impact of an 'innovation hurdle' on investment decisions is considered. Sections 5 and 6 look at different aspects of pharmaceutical output. Section 5 presents examples from different therapeutic classes to illustrate the innovation continuum. Many new indications and uses for therapies are only revealed after marketing, as are the relative merits of drugs competing in the same therapeutic class. Evaluating drugs pre-market launch, would risk excluding potentially worthwhile innovations. In Section 6, economic and therapeutic benefits of having multiple products in any one therapeutic class are discussed and set against the possible disadvantages. The conclusions drawn from this analysis are set out in Section 7.

Suggested Citation

  • Hannah Kettler, 1998. "Competition through Innovation, Innovation through Competition," Monograph 000434, Office of Health Economics.
  • Handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000434
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://www.ohe.org/publications/competition-through-innovation-innovation-through-competition/attachment-237-1998_competition_through_innovation_kettler_full/
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. David J. TEECE, 2008. "Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy," World Scientific Book Chapters, in: The Transfer And Licensing Of Know-How And Intellectual Property Understanding the Multinational Enterprise in the Modern World, chapter 5, pages 67-87, World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd..
    2. Clive Pritchard, 1998. "Trends in Economic Evaluation," Briefing 000444, Office of Health Economics.
    3. Keith Tolley;Gareth Morgan;Ray Cartwright;Rhys Williams, 1998. "Economic Aspects of Non-Hodgkin's Lymphoma," Series on Health 000436, Office of Health Economics.
    4. George Teeling Smith, 1992. "Innovative Competition in Medicine," Monograph 000397, Office of Health Economics.
    5. Michael F. Drummond;Adrian Towse, 1998. "From Efficacy to Cost-Effectiveness," Briefing 000438, Office of Health Economics.
    6. Helen Simpson, 1998. "Biotechnology and the Economics of Discovery in the Pharmaceutical Industry," Monograph 000432, Office of Health Economics.
    7. Nick Wells, 1988. "Innovative Chemical Extensions: The Economic Basis of Pharmaceutical Progress," Monograph 000365, Office of Health Economics.
    8. Robert Seitz;Hans-Helmut Konig;Eleni Jelastopulu, 1998. "Managed Care - An Option for the German Health Care System?," Monograph 000441, Office of Health Economics.
    9. Uwe Reinhardt, 1998. "Accountable Health Care: Is it compatible with social solidarity?," Monograph 000431, Office of Health Economics.
    10. Donald W. Light, 1998. "Effective Commissioning: Lessons from purchasing in American managed care," Monograph 000437, Office of Health Economics.
    11. Charles Webster, 1998. "National Health Service Reorganisation: Learning from History?," Monograph 000442, Office of Health Economics.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Hannah Kettler, 2000. "Narrowing the Gap between provision and need for medicines in developing countries," Monograph 000461, Office of Health Economics.
    2. Luiz Andrade & Catherine Sermet & Sylvain Pichetti, 2016. "Entry time effects and follow-on drug competition," The European Journal of Health Economics, Springer;Deutsche Gesellschaft für Gesundheitsökonomie (DGGÖ), vol. 17(1), pages 45-60, January.
    3. Office of Health Economics, 1998. "Controlling NHS Expenditure: The Impact of Labour’s NHS White Papers," Monograph 000435, Office of Health Economics.
    4. Jim Attridge, 2007. "Innovation Models In The Biopharmaceutical Sector," International Journal of Innovation Management (ijim), World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd., vol. 11(02), pages 215-243.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Office of Health Economics, 1998. "Controlling NHS Expenditure: The Impact of Labour’s NHS White Papers," Monograph 000435, Office of Health Economics.
    2. Nick Marchant, 1998. "Tuberculosis," Series on Health 000445, Office of Health Economics.
    3. Hannah Kettler, 1999. "Updating the Cost of a New Chemical Entity," Monograph 000456, Office of Health Economics.
    4. Martin Cave;Adrian Towse, 1997. "Regulating Prices Paid by the NHS for Medicines Supplied by the UK-Based Pharmaceutical Industry," Briefing 000427, Office of Health Economics.
    5. S. Arunachalam & Sridhar N. Ramaswami & Pol Herrmann & Doug Walker, 2018. "Innovation pathway to profitability: the role of entrepreneurial orientation and marketing capabilities," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, Springer, vol. 46(4), pages 744-766, July.
    6. Krickx, Guido A., 1995. "Vertical integration in the computer mainframe industry: A transaction cost interpretation," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Elsevier, vol. 26(1), pages 75-91, January.
    7. Soufiane Mezzourh & Walid A Nakara, 2009. "Governance and innovation : A Knowledge-based approach [La gouvernance de l'innovation : une approche par la connaissance]," Post-Print halshs-01955966, HAL.
    8. Hua Tang, 2022. "The Effect of ESG Performance on Corporate Innovation in China: The Mediating Role of Financial Constraints and Agency Cost," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 14(7), pages 1-21, March.
    9. Morricone, Serena & Munari, Federico & Oriani, Raffaele & de Rassenfosse, Gaetan, 2017. "Commercialization Strategy and IPO Underpricing," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 46(6), pages 1133-1141.
    10. Kuosmanen, Natalia & Valmari, Nelli, 2023. "Renewal of Companies Through Product Switching," ETLA Working Papers 104, The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy.
    11. Tarifa Fernández, Jorge & de Burgos Jiménez, Jerónimo & Céspedes Lorente, José Joaquín, 2018. "Absorptive capacity as a confounder of the process of supply chain integration," MPRA Paper 120125, University Library of Munich, Germany, revised 2018.
    12. Laura Barbieri & Daniela Bragoli & Flavia Cortelezzi & Giovanni Marseguerra, 2015. "Public Support to Innovation Strategies," DISCE - Quaderni del Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche e Sociali dises1509, Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Dipartimenti e Istituti di Scienze Economiche (DISCE).
    13. Baldwin, Carliss Y. & Bogers, Marcel L.A.M. & Kapoor, Rahul & West, Joel, 2024. "Focusing the ecosystem lens on innovation studies," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 53(3).
    14. Massimo Colombo & Annalisa Croce & Samuele Murtinu, 2014. "Ownership structure, horizontal agency costs and the performance of high-tech entrepreneurial firms," Small Business Economics, Springer, vol. 42(2), pages 265-282, February.
    15. Ariño, Africa & García-Canal, Esteban & Valdes, Ana, 1999. "Longevity of strategic alliances between competitors: A dynamic value creation approach," IESE Research Papers D/404, IESE Business School.
    16. Zemsky, Peter & Adner, Ron, 2003. "Disruptive Technologies and the Emergence of Competition," CEPR Discussion Papers 3994, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    17. Frida Thomas Pacho, 2018. "Diversified Network Effects on Innovation Performance in Tanzania: Innovation Strategy in Service Firms," Journal of Entrepreneurship and Business Innovation, Macrothink Institute, Journal of Entrepreneurship and Business Innovation, vol. 5(1), pages 1-1, December.
    18. Dwibedy, Punyashlok, 2022. "Informal competition and product innovation decisions of new ventures and incumbents across developing and transitioning countries," Journal of Business Venturing Insights, Elsevier, vol. 17(C).
    19. Richard Harris & John Moffat, 2011. "R&D, Innovation and Exporting," SERC Discussion Papers 0073, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
    20. Iain M. Cockburn & Megan J. MacGarvie, 2011. "Entry and Patenting in the Software Industry," Management Science, INFORMS, vol. 57(5), pages 915-933, May.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Competition through Innovation; Innovation through Competition;

    JEL classification:

    • I1 - Health, Education, and Welfare - - Health

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000434. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Publications Manager (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ohecouk.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.