IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ohe/monogr/000462.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Prices, Competition and Regulation in Pharmaceuticals: A Cross-National Comparison

Author

Listed:
  • Patricia Danzon;Li-Wei Chao

Abstract

Most countries regulate manufacturer prices for pharmaceuticals, either directly (France, Italy) or indirectly through controls on reimbursement (Germany, Japan) or profits (the UK). It is widely believed that drug prices are lower in countries with strict price regulation than in countries with less restrictive regulation (the UK) or no regulation (the US). For example, the BEUC (1989b) concluded that prices in the UK and the US were, respectively, 20 and 54 percent above the EEC average, whereas those in France and Italy were, respectively, 30 and 28 percent below the EEC average. The US General Accounting Office (GAO, 1992, 1994a) concluded that prices in the US in 1992 were 32 percent higher than prices in Canada and 60 percent higher than prices in the UK. A UK Department of Health study (DOH, 1997) concluded that US prices 88 percent higher than the UK in 1992. A recent US study (US H.R. Minority Staff, 1998) reported that drug prices in the US were 70 percent higher than in Canada and 102 percent higher than in Mexico. In the US, these studies have contributed to proposals (so far not enacted) for drug price controls – for example, President Clinton’s Health Security Act (1993) and the Prescription Drug Fairness Act of 1999 (H.R.644). In addition to these comparisons of average price levels, a growing number of countries, including Italy, Spain, the Netherlands, Canada and Japan, use international comparisons in their regulation of prices for individual drugs. The first purpose of this paper is to report indexes of manufacturer-level drug prices for six major markets – the UK, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, and Japan – relative to the US, using comprehensive data and more appropriate methods than those used in previous studies. Our data are from Intercontinental Medical Systems (IMS), a market research firm that collects data on drug sales worldwide. IMS data for all outpatient drug sales in 1992 are used to construct price indexes based on all molecules that match across the countries under comparison, including branded products (whether sold by the originator company or a licensee, hereafter ‘originator’ and ‘licensed’ products) and generic products, and all formulations, strengths and packs. Standard price indexes, weighted by either US consumption patterns or the comparison country's consumption, are computed. The indexes with US quantity weights show average prices for each country, relative to the US, as follows: the UK –17 percent, Canada +2 percent; Germany +25 percent; France –32 percent; Italy –13 percent; and Japan –12 percent. Thus this analysis, using a comprehensive market basket including generics and appropriate weighting, shows that crossnational price differences are less than suggested by previous studies. The indexes with UK consumption weights show the UK either lowest based on price per gram or third lowest, after France and Italy, based on price per pill. The bias in previous studies for the US is shown to result from selection of very small, unrepresentative samples of leading branded products, exclusion of all generics, and reporting of unweighted averages which give undue weight to the highest priced products. The Appendix to this paper details the differences between our price comparisons and those made by the GAO and BEUC. The cross-national diversity in range of products available and in patterns of drug consumption implies that there is no single ‘correct’ measure of price differences. Methodological judgements are unavoidable – in particular, choice of sample, weights and measure of price - and the most appropriate measure depends on the perspective of the analysis. However, while some choices depend on perspective, the analysis here clearly shows that a robust estimate should be based on a representative sample, including generics, and standard weighted indexes, not simple averages, as used in BEUC (1989), GAO (1992) and the OECD Pharmaceutical Purchasing Power Parities (OECD, 1993). The second purpose of this paper is to examine the extent of competition under alternative regulatory regimes. Regulation is often rationalised by the assumption that price competition is weak because: insurance makes patients insensitive to prices; physicians who are primary decision-makers may not know product prices and/or may be imperfect agents for patients; patents intentionally limit competition from generically equivalent substitutes; and therapeutic substitutes are imperfect. Retail pharmacy prices and other aspects of retail pharmacy are also regulated in countries that regulate manufacturer prices. Previous studies have found evidence of price competition in the UK, the US and Germany (Reekie, 1996; Towse and Leighton, 1999). However, both theory and casual empirical evidence suggest that strict price regulation may undermine competition. Generic market shares of off-patent products are significantly lower in countries with strict price or reimbursement regulation, such as France, Italy or Japan, than in the US, the UK, Canada and Germany, which have less strict price regulation. Whether regulation reinforces or undermines competition is an important empirical question, as different countries evaluate possible changes in their regulatory regimes. This paper estimates the effects of generic competition, therapeutic competition and other factors in the seven countries with their different regulatory regimes. The main findings are that generic competition significantly reduces prices in countries with free pricing (the US) and moderately constrained pricing (the UK, Germany and Canada), whereas generic competition is ineffective and may be counterproductive in countries with strict price or reimbursement regulation (France, Italy and Japan). One plausible explanation is that in regulatory regimes that drive down the originator price over the life-cycle, generic equivalents are often licensed co-marketers or minor ‘new’ versions of old molecules introduced by manufacturers as a strategy to obtain a higher regulated price. By contrast, in countries with free pricing and price sensitive purchasers, generic entrants must compete on price to gain market share. For therapeutic substitutes, the results here confirm previous findings (Reekie, 1996; Towse and Leighton, 1999) that successive molecules to enter a therapeutic category do so at lower prices than those of established entrants. This analysis has important implications for the methodology of drug price comparisons and for policy. First, robust price comparisons require representative samples and standard indexes. Limiting the sample to leading branded products and use of unweighted averages can yield very misleading results that tend to systematically overestimate prices in unregulated or less regulated markets, compared to strictly regulated markets. Second, regulation clearly undermines competition in the off-patent, multisource sector, which is contrary to sound economics and to the stated aim of policy in most countries. Innovative products are appropriately protected from generic competition for the life of the patent, in order to yield a return on R&D investments. However once the patent has expired, price competition between generic substitutes can yield significant savings to consumers and payers. Off-patent drugs account for 88 percent of reimbursable packs sold on average for member states of the EU (European Commission, 1998), and this off-patent share is expected to grow as patents expire on many of the current leading drugs. Increasing competition in the off-patent sector to free up ‘headroom’ in public budgets to pay for innovative, patent-protected products was suggested by the Bangemann Round Table discussions on the European single market for pharmaceuticals (European Commission, 1998; Danzon, 1998). Designing regulatory systems to promote competition in the off-patent sector is an important issue for all governments concerned with obtaining maximum value from health spending. The evidence here suggests that useful pro-competitive strategies include: (1) permitting pharmacists to substitute between generically-equivalent products (generic substitution), unless the physician indicates otherwise; and (2) promoting competition in retail pharmacy, by deregulating dispensing fees. For the on-patent sector, policy conclusions are more tentative because the empirical evidence is less robust and because optimal competition policy must weigh the consumer benefits of lower prices against the need to provide an opportunity for originator firms to recoup their R&D investments, which is the intent of patent protection. Whether pharmaceutical prices should differ between countries and, if so, the appropriate magnitude of such differences, has been addressed elsewhere (Danzon, 1997b, c) and is not discussed in detail here. Economic theory indicates that uniform prices would not be optimal and that price differences (Ramsey pricing) for patented products are the most efficient practical strategy to pay for the common costs of R&D that serve all consumers. The potential for price differences within the EU arises because health care is a national policy prerogative and different countries have pursued very different regulatory strategies. The growth of parallel trade, whereby wholesalers import products from lower-priced to higher-priced countries has narrowed sustainable differences, particularly on high-volume branded products. Regulation based on cross-national price comparisons has similar effects. Because of both of these factors, a comparison based solely on recently-launched branded products might show smaller differences between EU countries than the differences reported here based on 1992 prices which may still reflect, via the older products, the regulatory regimes and exchange rates that prevailed in the 1980s . Although the price data used here may not accurately reflect current price differentials on newly-launched products, these data do show the methodological issues raised by cross-national price comparisons and the biases in previous comparisons, as well as the broad effects of regulatory systems on competition. The report is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 reports price and quantity indexes, and compares the results here with those in previous cross-national price comparisons. Section 4 outlines a simple model of drug prices and the expected effects of regulation. Section 5 describes the empirical model and methods. Section 6 reports product-level regression analysis of product prices and tests for significant differences between countries. Section 7 reports similar analysis for prices at the molecule level, where the molecule price is a weighted average over all products in the molecule. Section 8 concludes.

Suggested Citation

  • Patricia Danzon;Li-Wei Chao, 2000. "Prices, Competition and Regulation in Pharmaceuticals: A Cross-National Comparison," Monograph 000462, Office of Health Economics.
  • Handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000462
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://www.ohe.org/publications/prices-competition-and-regulation-pharmaceuticals-cross-national-comparison/attachment-265-2000_prices_competition_regs_danzon/
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. W. Duncan Reekie, 1997. "Cartels, Spontaneous Price Discrimination and International Pharmacy Retailing," International Journal of the Economics of Business, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 4(3), pages 279-285.
    2. F. M. Scherer, 1997. "How US Antitrust Can Go Astray: The Brand Name Prescription Drug Litigation," International Journal of the Economics of Business, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 4(3), pages 239-256.
    3. Griliches, Zvi & Cockburn, Iain, 1994. "Generics and New Goods in Pharmaceutical Price Indexes," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 84(5), pages 1213-1232, December.
    4. Leibowitz, Arleen & Manning, Willard G. & Newhouse, Joseph P., 1985. "The demand for prescription drugs as a function of cost-sharing," Social Science & Medicine, Elsevier, vol. 21(10), pages 1063-1069, January.
    5. David Dranove & David Meltzer, 1994. "Do Important Drugs Reach the Market Sooner?," RAND Journal of Economics, The RAND Corporation, vol. 25(3), pages 402-423, Autumn.
    6. Patricia Danzon, 1997. "Trade and Price Differentials for Pharmaceuticals: Policy Options," Monograph 000430, Office of Health Economics.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Frances Ruane & Xiaoheng Zhang, 2007. "Where do MNEs Expand Production: Location Choices of the Pharmaceutical Industry in Europe after 1992," Papers WP211, Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI).
    2. Sun-Hong Kwon & Hea-Sun Park & Young-Jin Na & Chul Park & Ju-Young Shin & Hye-Lin Kim, 2021. "Price Reduction of Anticancer Drugs from 2007 to 2019 in South Korea: The Impact of Pharmaceutical Cost-Containment Policies," Applied Health Economics and Health Policy, Springer, vol. 19(3), pages 439-450, May.
    3. Alexandru Burcea & Ioana Boeraş & Claudia-Maria Mihuţ & Doru Bănăduc & Claudiu Matei & Angela Curtean-Bănăduc, 2020. "Adding the Mureş River Basin (Transylvania, Romania) to the List of Hotspots with High Contamination with Pharmaceuticals," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 12(23), pages 1-19, December.
    4. Frances Ruane & Xiaoheng Zhang, 2007. "Location Choices of the Pharmaceutical Industry in Europe after 1992," The Institute for International Integration Studies Discussion Paper Series iiisdp220, IIIS.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Danzon, Patricia M & Chao, Li-Wei, 2000. "Does Regulation Drive out Competition in Pharmaceutical Markets?," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 43(2), pages 311-357, October.
    2. Patricia M. Danzon & Y. Richard Wang & Liang Wang, 2005. "The impact of price regulation on the launch delay of new drugs—evidence from twenty‐five major markets in the 1990s," Health Economics, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., vol. 14(3), pages 269-292, March.
    3. Patricia M. Danzon & Eric L. Keuffel, 2014. "Regulation of the Pharmaceutical-Biotechnology Industry," NBER Chapters, in: Economic Regulation and Its Reform: What Have We Learned?, pages 407-484, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    4. Danzon, Patricia M. & Chao, Li-Wei, 2000. "Cross-national price differences for pharmaceuticals: how large, and why?," Journal of Health Economics, Elsevier, vol. 19(2), pages 159-195, March.
    5. Stéphane Jacobzone, 1998. "Le rôle des prix dans la régulation du secteur pharmaceutique," Économie et Statistique, Programme National Persée, vol. 312(1), pages 35-53.
    6. Ando, Amy, 1998. "Delay on the Path to the Endangered Species List: Do Costs and Benefits Matter," RFF Working Paper Series dp-97-43-rev, Resources for the Future.
    7. Berndt Ernst R. & Cockburn Iain M. & Cocks Douglas L. & Epstein Arnold M. & Griliches Zvi, 1998. "Is Price Inflation Different for the Elderly? An Empirical Analysis of Prescription Drugs," Forum for Health Economics & Policy, De Gruyter, vol. 1(1), pages 1-45, January.
    8. Nebibe Varol & Joan Costa-i-Font & Alistair McGuire, 2011. "Explaining Early Adoption on New Medicines: Regulation, Innovation and Scale," CESifo Working Paper Series 3459, CESifo.
    9. Perloff, Jeffrey M. & Suslow, Valerie Y. & Seguin, Paul J., 1995. "Higher Prices from Entry: Pricing of Brand-Name Drugs," Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UC Berkeley, Working Paper Series qt75g4k1nt, Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UC Berkeley.
    10. Iain M. Cockburn & Jean O. Lanjouw & Mark Schankerman, 2016. "Patents and the Global Diffusion of New Drugs," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 106(1), pages 136-164, January.
    11. Antonio Cabrales, 2003. "Pharmaceutical generics, vertical product differentiation and public policy," Economics Working Papers 662, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.
    12. Claudia Allende & Juan Pablo Atal & Rodrigo Carril & Jose Ignacio Cuesta & Andrés González Lira, 2023. "Drivers of public procurement prices: Evidence from pharmaceutical markets," Economics Working Papers 1874, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.
    13. Joan Costa-i-Font & Alistair McGuire & Nebibe Varol, 2011. "Does Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Affect the Adoption of Generic Competition? Evidence from the OECD, 1999-2008," CESifo Working Paper Series 3441, CESifo.
    14. Ernst R. Berndt & David M. Cutler & Richard Frank & Zvi Griliches & Joseph P. Newhouse & Jack E. Triplett, 2001. "Price Indexes for Medical Care Goods and Services -- An Overview of Measurement Issues," NBER Chapters, in: Medical Care Output and Productivity, pages 141-200, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    15. Pierre Régibeau & Katharine Rockett, 2010. "Innovation Cycles And Learning At The Patent Office: Does The Early Patent Get The Delay?," Journal of Industrial Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 58(2), pages 222-246, June.
    16. Crown William H. & Berndt Ernst R. & Baser Onur & Finkelstein Stan N. & Witt Whitney P. & Maguire Jonathan & Haver Kenan E., 2004. "Benefit Plan Design and Prescription Drug Utilization Among Asthmatics: Do Patient Copayments Matter?," Forum for Health Economics & Policy, De Gruyter, vol. 7(1), pages 1-35, January.
    17. Alan, Sule & Crossley, Thomas F. & Grootendorst, Paul & Veall, Michael R., 2002. "The effects of drug subsidies on out-of-pocket prescription drug expenditures by seniors: regional evidence from Canada," Journal of Health Economics, Elsevier, vol. 21(5), pages 805-826, September.
    18. Joseph Dimasi & Henry Grabowski & John Vernon, 1995. "R&D Costs, Innovative Output and Firm Size in the Pharmaceutical Industry," International Journal of the Economics of Business, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 2(2), pages 201-219.
    19. Li, M. & Ohkusa, Y., 2000. "An Empirical Research of Substitutability between Medical Services and Over-the-Counter Medication. An Analysis of Thirteen Different Minor Ailments," ISER Discussion Paper 0522, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University.
    20. Shane Greenstein & Ryan C. McDevitt, 2009. "The Broadband Bonus: Accounting for Broadband Internet's Impact on U.S. GDP," NBER Working Papers 14758, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Prices; Competition and Regulation in Pharmaceuticals: A Cross-National Comparison;

    JEL classification:

    • I1 - Health, Education, and Welfare - - Health

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000462. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Publications Manager (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ohecouk.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.