IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/eep/report/rr2010113.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Pollution Control and Sustainable Fisheries Management in Southern Songkhla Lake, Thailand

Author

Listed:
  • Kunlayanee Pornpinatepong

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Sakchai Kiripat

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Sinad Treewanchai

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Sukampon Chongwilaikasaem

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Chotima Pornsawang

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Pathomwat Chantarasap

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Chantip Chandee

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

  • Pornchanok Jantrakul

    (Department of Economics, Prince of Songkla University, Hat Yai, Songkhla)

Abstract

The major objective of this study was to develop appropriate water quality control policies for a sustainable fishery in Southern Songkhla Lake (Southern Lake) so the impact of water pollution on fishery production in the lake was the first consideration. The three major components of this study were: (i) the identification of the situation and trends in fishery production associated with water quality in the lake, using secondary data and statistical analysis, (ii) the evaluation of technological options to improve water quality using secondary data and cost-effectiveness analysis, and (iii) the analysis of proposed policy alternatives for better water quality. In order to identify the current situation and trends in fishery production associated with water quality in Southern Lake, the natural shrimp catch was used as an indicator of water quality deterioration while the water quality composite index (WQCI) was used as the indicator of the relationship between water quality and pollution from various sources. Our statistical analysis indicated that the water quality changes in the lake had a significant impact on shrimp production, i.e., one unit increase in the WQCI at UTapao would lead to a shrimp productivity increase of 3.4% (significant at the 0.05 level), and one unit increase in the WQCI at Pag-ro would lead to a shrimp productivity increase of 10% (significant at the 0.01 level). Also, an analysis of 12 years of water quality data (1992-2004) found that the amount of nitrogen and phosphate discharged into Southern Lake had increased over time at every river mouth. In particular, the total amount of nitrogen at the U-Tapao river mouth had increased significantly. Nitrogen was found in farm effluents and in both domestic and industrial waste and in large amounts, which was very harmful to aquatic animals. Therefore, in order to control and improve the water quality of Southern Lake, the wastewater from the various sources needs to be well managed in order to increase the fishery value of the lake. There were two types of methodologies identified which affected treatment costs for basic technology options. First, land use applications had a higher fixed cost due to land use but lower operating costs, while technology-based applications, such as the Up-flow Anaerobic Sludge Blanket (UASB) or Activated Sludge (AS), had lower land use costs but higher operating costs. With high technology options, however, there was no particular cost pattern. The results of the cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) showed that the effectiveness of a treatment technology was sensitive to the size of the plant and the influent load. It was less effective for businesses with a lower influent load or a smaller size to invest in individual treatment plants while it was more cost-effective for smallscale polluters to share a common treatment plant. For domestic treatment facilities at the municipal level, the CEA showed that the cost of treating the biological oxygen demand (BOD) per kilogram was very high even at full capacity. Large-scale domestic treatment facilities tended to be ineffective due to under-utilization and such operations required effective administrative management. Smaller-scale domestic treatment facilities are recommended because these are easier to operate effectively and also offer more flexibility for future development. The command and control (CAC) policy is the current water pollution management system in Southern Lake. Overall, this study found that the CAC policy was deficient in encouraging the participation of all stakeholders and that they were not sufficiently aware of their responsibilities in environmental protection Based on our literature review and survey, it became evident that firms and farms had the potential to improve their wastewater treatment technologies but there were no incentives for them to do so. Market-based instruments have many advantages over CAC regulations. However, each instrument has different advantages and disadvantages. Therefore, three policy alternatives were carefully compared: the command and control (CAC) system, emission charge system (ECS) and tradable discharge permit (TDP) system. There were ten criteria selected to compare the different policies, namely, public acceptability, legal feasibility, implementation complexity, effectiveness, capital costs, operating costs, transaction costs, impacts, equity, and decentralization. In order to select the best alternative, the study suggests that policy-makers apply different weights to the different criteria depending on their desired goals. Moreover, some congruence among the advantages of each policy option can also be considered. For example, due to the high outcome effectiveness of the TDP and high capital costs, it could best be applied to large-sized firms and farms, while the ECS would better suit small and medium-scale firms and farms because it involves lower capital costs. Whichever combination of policy options is ultimately selected, further studies will be needed to determine the effectiveness of such combinations.

Suggested Citation

  • Kunlayanee Pornpinatepong & Sakchai Kiripat & Sinad Treewanchai & Sukampon Chongwilaikasaem & Chotima Pornsawang & Pathomwat Chantarasap & Chantip Chandee & Pornchanok Jantrakul, 2010. "Pollution Control and Sustainable Fisheries Management in Southern Songkhla Lake, Thailand," EEPSEA Research Report rr2010113, Economy and Environment Program for Southeast Asia (EEPSEA), revised Nov 2010.
  • Handle: RePEc:eep:report:rr2010113
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://www.eepsea.org/pub/rr/2010-RR5-Kunlayanee.pdf
    File Function: First version, 2010
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Ian J. Bateman & Richard T. Carson & Brett Day & Michael Hanemann & Nick Hanley & Tannis Hett & Michael Jones-Lee & Graham Loomes, 2002. "Economic Valuation with Stated Preference Techniques," Books, Edward Elgar Publishing, number 2639.
    2. Felder, Stefan & Schleiniger, Reto, 2002. "Environmental tax reform: efficiency and political feasibility," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 42(1-2), pages 107-116, August.
    3. Stefan Felder & Reto Schleiniger, "undated". "Environmental Tax Reform: Efficiency and Political Feasibility," IEW - Working Papers 013, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics - University of Zurich.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. A. Lans Bovenberg & Lawrence H. Goulder, 2001. "Neutralizing the Adverse Industry Impacts of CO2 Abatement Policies: What Does It Cost?," NBER Chapters, in: Behavioral and Distributional Effects of Environmental Policy, pages 45-90, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    2. Hickson, Allister, 2006. "Motor vehicle insurance rating with pseudo emissions coverage," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 58(1), pages 146-159, June.
    3. Mark Sommer & Kurt Kratena, 2020. "Consumption and production-based CO2 pricing policies: macroeconomic trade-offs and carbon leakage," Economic Systems Research, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 32(1), pages 29-57, January.
    4. Kirchner, Mathias & Sommer, Mark & Kratena, Kurt & Kletzan-Slamanig, Daniela & Kettner-Marx, Claudia, 2019. "CO2 taxes, equity and the double dividend – Macroeconomic model simulations for Austria," Energy Policy, Elsevier, vol. 126(C), pages 295-314.
    5. Michaelowa, Axel & Michaelowa, Katharina, 2011. "Coding Error or Statistical Embellishment? The Political Economy of Reporting Climate Aid," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 39(11), pages 2010-2020.
    6. Liang, Qiao-Mei & Fan, Ying & Wei, Yi-Ming, 2007. "Carbon taxation policy in China: How to protect energy- and trade-intensive sectors?," Journal of Policy Modeling, Elsevier, vol. 29(2), pages 311-333.
    7. Cathrine Hagem & Michael Hoel & Thomas Sterner, 2020. "Refunding Emission Payments: Output-Based Versus Expenditure-Based Refunding," Environmental & Resource Economics, Springer;European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, vol. 77(3), pages 641-667, November.
    8. Bornstein, Nicholas & Lanz, Bruno, 2008. "Voting on the environment: Price or ideology? Evidence from Swiss referendums," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 67(3), pages 430-440, October.
    9. Andrea Kollmann & Friedrich Schneider, 2010. "Why Does Environmental Policy in Representative Democracies Tend to Be Inadequate? A Preliminary Public Choice Analysis," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 2(12), pages 1-25, November.
    10. Ghesla, Claus & Grieder, Manuel & Schmitz, Jan & Stadelmann, Marcel, 2020. "Pro-environmental incentives and loss aversion: A field experiment on electricity saving behavior," Energy Policy, Elsevier, vol. 137(C).
    11. Geir H. Bjertnæs, 2005. "Avoiding Adverse Employment Effects from Energy Taxation: What does it cost?," Discussion Papers 432, Statistics Norway, Research Department.
    12. Bjertnæs, Geir H., 2011. "Avoiding adverse employment effects from electricity taxation in Norway: What does it cost?," Energy Policy, Elsevier, vol. 39(9), pages 4766-4773, September.
    13. Jollands, Nigel, 2006. "Concepts of efficiency in ecological economics: Sisyphus and the decision maker," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 56(3), pages 359-372, March.
    14. Hagem, Cathrine & Hoel, Michael & Holtsmark, Bjart & Sterner, Thomas, 2015. "Refunding Emissions Payments," RFF Working Paper Series dp-15-05, Resources for the Future.
    15. Bjertnæs, Geir H. & Fæhn, Taran, 2008. "Energy taxation in a small, open economy: Social efficiency gains versus industrial concerns," Energy Economics, Elsevier, vol. 30(4), pages 2050-2071, July.
    16. Reto Schleiniger & Stefan Felder, "undated". "Fossile Energiepolitik jenseits von Kyoto," IEW - Working Papers 078, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics - University of Zurich.
    17. Sterner, Thomas & Hoglund Isaksson, Lena, 2006. "Refunded emission payments theory, distribution of costs, and Swedish experience of NOx abatement," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 57(1), pages 93-106, April.
    18. Alexeev, Alexander & Good, David H. & Krutilla, Kerry, 2016. "Environmental taxation and the double dividend in decentralized jurisdictions," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 122(C), pages 90-100.
    19. Liu, Yang & Han, Liyan & Yin, Ziqiao & Luo, Kongyi, 2017. "A competitive carbon emissions scheme with hybrid fiscal incentives: The evidence from a taxi industry," Energy Policy, Elsevier, vol. 102(C), pages 414-422.
    20. Mathias Kirchner & Mark Sommer & Claudia Kettner-Marx & Daniela Kletzan-Slamanig & Katharina Köberl & Kurt Kratena, 2018. "CO2 Tax Scenarios for Austria. Impacts on Household Income Groups, CO2 Emissions, and the Economy," WIFO Working Papers 558, WIFO.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    pollution; waste; Thailand;
    All these keywords.

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:eep:report:rr2010113. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Arief Anshory yusuf (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/eepsesg.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.