IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/h/era/chaptr/2022-cadp-8.html
   My bibliography  Save this book chapter

Innovation Systems and Digital Transformation

In: The Comprehensive Asia Development Plan (CADP) 3.0: Towards an Integrated, Innovative, Inclusive, and Sustainable Economy

Author

Listed:
  • Keita Oikawa

    (Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA))

Abstract

When you hear the word ‘innovative’, what comes to mind? You may think of a firm providing products or services by making full use of state-of-the-art technologies such as artificial intelligence (AI) or a firm producing such technologies. Innovation is a key growth factor not only for firms but also for nations. Innovative firms generate more value added than non-innovative firms. The more innovative firms there are in an economy, the more qualitative products and services are provided to the market with a more efficient method of production, which means the better the living standards (income levels) the people living in the economy enjoy. An innovative nation or economy has an environment conductive to generating innovative firms. It has highly competitive universities attracting talented people. It generates many start-ups, and venture capitalists gather there. When looking at innovative economies, we find that systematic linkages exist between universities, firms, investors, and related organisations. This finding applies not only to established developed countries like the G7 members, but also to newly developed countries like the Asian Miracles – the Republic of Korea (henceforth, Korea), Taiwan, Singapore, and Hong Kong. This chapter discusses optimal innovation systems at the macroeconomic level for middle-income Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) Member States (AMS). As an introduction, we give a brief overview of the discussion. Many AMS are middleincome countries, and their technology utilisation levels are much lower than those of high-income advanced countries such as the United States (US). Economic growth theory implies that closing this technology utilisation gap is a primary way of turning middle-income countries into high-income countries as quickly as possible. For middleincome AMS to improve their technology utilisation levels, they need to understand the mechanism of technology adoption – both at the firm level and at the macroeconomic level – and build their innovation systems by harnessing digital transformation. Many AMS have advanced to middle-income status by participating in global value chains, based on their comparative advantage in labour costs amid globalisation. More precisely, AMS have improved their income levels by attracting foreign direct investment (FDI) to manufacturing plants through competitive multinational enterprises by providing low-cost labour resources. Moreover, indigenous firms that trade with global firms have improved their productivity through learning effects. It may appear that this growth model is sufficient for economies to grow to high-income levels since advanced technologies are likely to flow to AMS through FDI, typically in the manufacturing sector. However, what we have observed is the middle-income AMS struggling with overcoming the ‘middle-income trap’. In examining the differences between Asian Miracles cases and economies that remain at middle-income levels, it is difficult to find economies that have reached high-income levels through FDI alone. All the Asian Miracles that succeeded in establishing innovation systems, building innovation capabilities, and fostering competitive private firms in their countries did so by developing a healthy competitive market environment. For middle-income AMS to develop innovation-friendly markets, they need to keep in mind the lessons from empirical studies regarding technology diffusion from global frontier firms to national firms. First, promoting global-level firms in a country benefits other national firms – although national laggers seem to have difficulty adopting technologies directly from global frontier firms. Second, fostering global-level firms requires encouraging entrepreneurship, FDI for global innovative enterprises, an improved educational system, research and development (R&D) activities, industry–university R&D partnership, and an effective intellectual property rights system. Third, minimising inefficient and incapable firms contributes to improvements in macro-level innovation capabilities. To do so, it is necessary to balance the benefits of employment protection and costs of employment allocation inefficiency regulations and to reduce administrative costs for businesses. Last, to help national laggers catch up, product market laws and employment protection must be relaxed and industry–university R&D cooperation must be encouraged. From the perspective of indigenous firms or start-ups hoping to be global-level innovative firms in their economies, it is difficult for them to avoid competing with global frontier firms in high-tech industries, such as electronics, machinery, pharmaceuticals, aerospace, transport equipment, software, information technology (IT), and science and technical services. Competitive firms in both the Asian Miracles – Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan – and China undertook creative imitation innovation strategies,and can provide lessons for latecomer firms competing with advanced firms in high-tech industry markets. Creative imitation is an innovative activity in which latecomers try to partly imitate and adapt new products and services from abroad to satisfy local market demands or to create lower-cost versions to compete in price-sensitive markets. It is an important option for firms in the middle-income AMS. Another important point in the promotion of innovative firms is full utilisation of digital transformation. The Asian Miracles succeeded in reaching the technological frontier before or around the 1990s, before the information and communication technology (ICT) revolution started in full swing. The current digital transformation trend has changed the importance of start-ups relative to incumbent firms in innovation compared with the Asian Miracle era. The significance of start-ups has been a major driver of innovation, especially in sectors such as e-commerce, mobile applications, finance, and the internet of things. ICT, or digital technology, has a property of general-purpose technology (GPT): it will be deployed in all sectors – both manufacturing and non-manufacturing – and make current business models obsolete. The digitalisation tide never turns, so both the private and public sectors in AMS economies must advance by shifting weight from accumulated ‘incremental’ innovation (typically in the manufacturing sector) to ‘disruptive’ digital innovation (adopted in all sectors). Technology utilisation gaps embody the potential to grow quickly by catching up with and even leapfrogging to a higher development stage – through the ‘advantage of backwardness’. To do this, AMS governments must keep in mind that supporting firms arbitrarily will not help to create innovative firms. Such industrial policies are not justified either theoretically or empirically. Pro-innovation industrial policies should keep the market competitive and impose strict accountability. In addition, AMS governments should establish innovation systems in which a government organisation oversees and coordinates the formulation and implementation of innovation policies across several government departments. They should also provide monetary incentives to the private sector, including local and international firms, to invest in R&D for innovation. Moreover, they should promote university–industry cooperation (UIC), which is an important component of innovation ecosystems that foster technological diffusion and knowledge spillover. This chapter is organised as follows. Section 2 breaks down productivity gaps into three factors – reproducible capital, human capital, and total factor productivity (TFP) – amongst AMS, East Asian countries, and the US. Section 3 claims the importance of TFP in economic growth by using macroeconomic models. Section 4 shows the movements of TFP of AMS and East Asian countries in recent decades. Section 5 explains the relationship between TFP and innovation capability, and shows what the ‘advantage of backwardness’ is via macroeconomic modelling. Section 6 presents a mathematical expression of macro-level innovation capability as the aggregation of individual firmlevel innovation capability, and discusses empirical findings on technology diffusion from global frontier firms and national firms. Section 7 explains that digital technology has the nature of GPT and discusses empirical findings regarding the relationship amongst digital technology adoption, firms’ capability, and market incentives. Section 8 discusses optimal innovation systems, harnessing digital transformation, for middle-income AMS to conclude this chapter.

Suggested Citation

  • Keita Oikawa, 2022. "Innovation Systems and Digital Transformation," Chapters, in: Fukunari Kimura & Keita Oikawa (ed.), The Comprehensive Asia Development Plan (CADP) 3.0: Towards an Integrated, Innovative, Inclusive, and Sustainable Economy, chapter 8, pages 237-276, Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA).
  • Handle: RePEc:era:chaptr:2022-cadp-8
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://www.eria.org/uploads/media/Books/2022-CADP-3/12_ch.8-Innovation-Systems.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Eric von Hippel, 1986. "Lead Users: A Source of Novel Product Concepts," Management Science, INFORMS, vol. 32(7), pages 791-805, July.
    2. Nicoletti, Giuseppe & von Rueden, Christina & Andrews, Dan, 2020. "Digital technology diffusion: A matter of capabilities, incentives or both?," European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 128(C).
    3. Robert M. Solow, 1956. "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 70(1), pages 65-94.
    4. Nobuya Fukugawa, 2018. "Division of Labor between Innovation Intermediaries for SMEs: Productivity Effects of Interfirm Organizations in Japan," Journal of Small Business Management, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 56(S1), pages 297-322, March.
    5. Marc Rysman, 2009. "The Economics of Two-Sided Markets," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 23(3), pages 125-143, Summer.
    6. Lurong Chen & Lydia Ruddy, 2020. "Improving Digital Connectivity: Policy Priority for ASEAN Digital Transformation," Working Papers PB-2020-07, Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA).
    7. Eric Bartelsman & Phoebus Dhrymes, 1998. "Productivity Dynamics: U.S. Manufacturing Plants, 1972–1986," Journal of Productivity Analysis, Springer, vol. 9(1), pages 5-34, January.
    8. Yasushi Ueki, 2020. "Production Networks and Technology Transfer: ―Empirical Analysis Based on Survey Data for Companies in Southeast Asia―," Public Policy Review, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance Japan, vol. 16(1), pages 95-120, February.
    9. Leonardo Iacovone & Gustavo A. Crespi, 2010. "Catching up with the technological frontier:Micro-level evidence on growth and convergence," Industrial and Corporate Change, Oxford University Press and the Associazione ICC, vol. 19(6), pages 2073-2096, December.
    10. Fukunari Kimura, 2020. "Exit Strategies for ASEAN Member States: Keeping Production Networks Alive Despite the Impending Demand Shock," Working Papers PB-2020-03, Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA).
    11. Lucia Foster & John C. Haltiwanger & C. J. Krizan, 2001. "Aggregate Productivity Growth: Lessons from Microeconomic Evidence," NBER Chapters, in: New Developments in Productivity Analysis, pages 303-372, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    12. Donald Siegel & Charles Wessner, 2012. "Universities and the success of entrepreneurial ventures: evidence from the small business innovation research program," The Journal of Technology Transfer, Springer, vol. 37(4), pages 404-415, August.
    13. Nicholas Bloom & Raffaella Sadun & John Van Reenen, 2012. "Americans Do IT Better: US Multinationals and the Productivity Miracle," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 102(1), pages 167-201, February.
    14. Moses Abramovitz, 1956. "Resource and Output Trends in the United States since 1870," NBER Books, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, number abra56-1, March.
    15. Lerner, Josh, 1999. "The Government as Venture Capitalist: The Long-Run Impact of the SBIR Program," The Journal of Business, University of Chicago Press, vol. 72(3), pages 285-318, July.
    16. MARTENS Bertin, 2020. "An economic perspective on data and platform market power," JRC Working Papers on Digital Economy 2020-09, Joint Research Centre.
    17. Bart van Ark & Mary O'Mahoney & Marcel P. Timmer, 2008. "The Productivity Gap between Europe and the United States: Trends and Causes," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 22(1), pages 25-44, Winter.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Young Eun Kim & Norman V. Loayza, 2019. "Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World," Revista Economía, Fondo Editorial - Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú, vol. 42(84), pages 36-93.
    2. Hulten, Charles R., 2010. "Growth Accounting," Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, in: Bronwyn H. Hall & Nathan Rosenberg (ed.), Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, edition 1, volume 2, chapter 0, pages 987-1031, Elsevier.
    3. Massimo Del Gatto & Adriana Di Liberto & Carmelo Petraglia, 2011. "Measuring Productivity," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 25(5), pages 952-1008, December.
    4. Steff De Visscher & Markus Eberhardt & Gerdie Everaert, 2017. "Measuring productivity and absorptive capacity evolution," Discussion Papers 2017-11, University of Nottingham, GEP.
    5. Eberhardt, Markus & Everaert, Gerdie & De Visscher, Stef, 2017. "Measuring Productivity and Absorptive Capacity Evolution in OECD Economies," CEPR Discussion Papers 12261, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    6. Jeffrey L. Furman, 2012. "The America COMPETES Acts: The Future of US Physical Science and Engineering Research?," NBER Chapters, in: Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 13, pages 101-149, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    7. Peter Bauer & Igor Fedotenkov & Aurelien Genty & Issam Hallak & Peter Harasztosi & David Martinez Turegano & David Nguyen & Nadir Preziosi & Ana Rincon-Aznar & Miguel Sanchez Martinez, 2020. "Productivity in Europe: Trends and drivers in a service-based economy," JRC Research Reports JRC119785, Joint Research Centre.
    8. Giovanni Dosi & Sébastien Lechevalier & Angelo Secchi, 2010. "Interfirm heterogeneity: nature, sources and consequences for industrial dynamics. An introduction," Université Paris1 Panthéon-Sorbonne (Post-Print and Working Papers) hal-00642680, HAL.
    9. Johanna Vogel, 2015. "The two faces of R&D and human capital: Evidence from Western European regions," Papers in Regional Science, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 94(3), pages 525-551, August.
    10. Alain de Serres & Naomitsu Yashiro & Hervé Boulhol, 2014. "An international perspective on the New Zealand productivity paradox," Working Papers 2014/01, New Zealand Productivity Commission.
    11. Jeffrey L. Furman, 2013. "The America COMPETES Acts: The Future of US Physical Science and Engineering Research?," Innovation Policy and the Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 13(1), pages 101-149.
    12. Feld, Lars P. & Schmidt, Christoph M. & Schnabel, Isabel & Truger, Achim & Wieland, Volker, 2019. "Den Strukturwandel meistern. Jahresgutachten 2019/20 [Dealing with Structural Change. Annual Report 2019/20]," Annual Economic Reports / Jahresgutachten, German Council of Economic Experts / Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, volume 127, number 201920.
    13. De Visscher, Stef & Eberhardt, Markus & Everaert, Gerdie, 2020. "Estimating and testing the multicountry endogenous growth model," Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol. 125(C).
    14. Georges Daw, 2024. "Impact of technical change via intermediate consumption: exhaustive general equilibrium growth accounting and reassessment applied to USA 1954–1990," Portuguese Economic Journal, Springer;Instituto Superior de Economia e Gestao, vol. 23(1), pages 55-87, January.
    15. Jan Fagerberg & Bengt-Åke Lundvall & Martin Srholec, 2018. "Global Value Chains, National Innovation Systems and Economic Development," The European Journal of Development Research, Palgrave Macmillan;European Association of Development Research and Training Institutes (EADI), vol. 30(3), pages 533-556, July.
    16. Kumar, Sanjesh & Singh, Baljeet, 2019. "Barriers to the international diffusion of technological innovations," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 82(C), pages 74-86.
    17. Roberto Martino & Phu Nguyen-Van, 2014. "Labour market regulation and fiscal parameters: A structural model for European regions," Working Papers of BETA 2014-19, Bureau d'Economie Théorique et Appliquée, UDS, Strasbourg.
    18. Kox, Henk L.M. & Leeuwen, George van & Wiel, Henry van der, 2010. "Competitive, but too small - productivity and entry-exit determinants in European business services," MPRA Paper 24389, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    19. Poschke, Markus, 2013. "The Decision to Become an Entrepreneur and the Firm Size Distribution: A Unifying Framework for Policy Analysis," IZA Discussion Papers 7757, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).
    20. Matthias Firgo & Peter Mayerhofer, 2015. "Wissens-Spillovers und regionale Entwicklung - welche strukturpolitische Ausrichtung optimiert des Wachstum?," Working Paper Reihe der AK Wien - Materialien zu Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 144, Kammer für Arbeiter und Angestellte für Wien, Abteilung Wirtschaftswissenschaft und Statistik.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:era:chaptr:2022-cadp-8. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Ranti Amelia (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/eriadid.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.