IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/
MyIDEAS: Login to save this paper or follow this series

Knowledge, Consumption, and Endogenous Growth

  • Richard N. Langlois

    (University of Connecticut)

The recent efflorescence of interest in "endogenous" theories of economic growth has focused attention on the nature and role of knowledge in the growth process (Romer 1986, 1990; Grossman and Helpman 1990, 1994). Unlike earlier models of growth (Solow 1956; Swan 1956) in which technological change appeared as an exogenous parameter, this New Growth Theory (NGT) has sought to "endogenize" technical change by folding its production more fully into the neoclassical positive heuristic. Knowledge no longer appears as manna from heaven, but is now produced just as are bananas and tires: as the result of the rational optimizing behavior of economic agents. These agents invest resources in Research and Development (R&D), a sausage machine whose output is new technological knowledge. For reasons that Kenneth Arrow (1962) long ago articulated, however, the good called knowledge has certain peculiar properties in that, once created, it can spill easily into the hands of others at zero marginal cost. This process of spillover (and the nonconvexity it implies) is the source of the increasing returns that generate economic growth. While not questioning some essential truth to this story, students of the process of technological change - especially those who have not restricted themselves to theoretical models - have expressed considerable doubt about the this picture of technological knowledge and its creation. Those who study the historical processes of technical change have found that knowledge does not always - and perhaps does not usually - take the form Arrow assumed (Nelson 1992). Much technological knowledge cannot in fact be transmitted easily to others; much technological knowledge is inarticulate and tacit (Polanyi 1958), and can be transmitted only at a cost through imitation and apprenticeship. This observation creates a difficulty for knowledge-based theories of growth. To the extent that knowledge is tacit in this way, it behaves like an ordinary private good, and its role in generating increasing returns is lost. One response to the problem of tacit knowledge among sophisticated students of innovation has been to create a clear distinction between knowledge that is tacit and knowledge that is codified. Codified knowledge is knowledge that has been (or can be) converted into symbols for easy transmission, replication, and storage (Boisot 1995; Saviotti 1998). Such knowledge thus partakes of Arrovian public-good properties, which makes it a potential source of increasing returns. Under this stratagem, the large place of tacit knowledge in social learning does not invalidate growth theory so long as there also exists codified knowledge in suitable quantities. Some writers would even go further, suggesting that technological change and economic growth have had the effect of tipping the balance between tacit and codified knowledge (Arora and Gambardella 1994; Cowan and Foray 1997). "More" knowledge is becoming codified, implying (and perhaps explaining) an accelerated pace of social learning and economic growth. This essay takes a more skeptical view of the proposition that we are experiencing greater codification hand in hand with modern technology and economic growth. But such skepticism need not have dire implications for (the theory of) economic growth. The essay will take an equally skeptical view of the proposition that only codified knowledge, and never tacit knowledge, can generate economic growth.

If you experience problems downloading a file, check if you have the proper application to view it first. In case of further problems read the IDEAS help page. Note that these files are not on the IDEAS site. Please be patient as the files may be large.

File URL: http://web2.uconn.edu/economics/working/2000-02.pdf
File Function: Full text
Download Restriction: no

Paper provided by University of Connecticut, Department of Economics in its series Working papers with number 2000-02.

as
in new window

Length: 38 pages
Date of creation: Jan 2000
Date of revision:
Handle: RePEc:uct:uconnp:2000-02
Contact details of provider: Postal: University of Connecticut 365 Fairfield Way, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT 06269-1063
Phone: (860) 486-4889
Fax: (860) 486-4463
Web page: http://www.econ.uconn.edu/

More information through EDIRC

No references listed on IDEAS
You can help add them by filling out this form.

This item is not listed on Wikipedia, on a reading list or among the top items on IDEAS.

When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:uct:uconnp:2000-02. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: (Francis Ahking)

If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

If references are entirely missing, you can add them using this form.

If the full references list an item that is present in RePEc, but the system did not link to it, you can help with this form.

If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

This information is provided to you by IDEAS at the Research Division of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis using RePEc data.