IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/sae/urbstu/v34y1997i12p1971-1986.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Public-Private Joint Ventures for High Volume Retailers: Who Benefits?

Author

Listed:
  • Allan Kotin

    (KMG Consulting, 12100 Wilshire Boulevard1050, Los Angeles, California 90025, USA, akotin@idt.net)

  • Richard Peiser

    (KMG Consulting, 12100 Wilshire Boulevard1050, Los Angeles, California 90025, USA, peiser@almaak.usc.edu)

Abstract

Retail development has become the preferred land use among Californian cities because the sales tax dollars generated by such development have the greatest impact on local budgets. This situation is a direct result of California's Proposition 13, passed in 1978, which limits property taxes to 1 per cent of the original purchase price of properties. The paper explores how the benefits of public assistance are distributed among the major parties to public-private joint ventures—the city, the anchor retailer and the developer. It attempts to answer the question, "Who really benefits from public assistance?" We focus on high volume retailers, sometimes referred to as 'big-box' retailers, because they represent a homogeneous class of public-private projects. The results show, somewhat surprisingly, that while the city's share of the benefits may have eroded, new performance-based incentives are being employed in public-private joint ventures that help to protect the city's share. The North County Square case study illustrates how new performance-based public-private deals are structured. The paper then compares the distribution of public tax benefits in four public-private transactions in California. The analysis shows a wide variation in the percentage of tax benefits that are retained by the city. In those situations where the city must compete with another city where the development will otherwise occur, the developer and the tenant are more likely to receive a large percentage of the total benefits. The case study demonstrates that cities do not necessarily have to receive a smaller and smaller share of the public benefit over time as tenants and developers become more sophisticated in playing off one city against another. Deal structures such as those presented here provide ample tools with which to protect the public's share of the benefits.

Suggested Citation

  • Allan Kotin & Richard Peiser, 1997. "Public-Private Joint Ventures for High Volume Retailers: Who Benefits?," Urban Studies, Urban Studies Journal Limited, vol. 34(12), pages 1971-1986, December.
  • Handle: RePEc:sae:urbstu:v:34:y:1997:i:12:p:1971-1986
    DOI: 10.1080/0042098975178
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1080/0042098975178
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1080/0042098975178?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Miceli, Thomas J., 1992. "Optimal fiscal zoning when the local government is a discriminating monopolist," Regional Science and Urban Economics, Elsevier, vol. 22(4), pages 579-596, November.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Hamid Hamoudi & Isabel Rodríguez & Marcos Sanz Martín-Bustamante, 2017. "Optimal Zoning in Spatial Differentiation," Estudios de Economia, University of Chile, Department of Economics, vol. 44(1 Year 20), pages 33-51, June.
    2. Lai, Fu-Chuan & Tsai, Jyh-Fa, 2004. "Duopoly locations and optimal zoning in a small open city," Journal of Urban Economics, Elsevier, vol. 55(3), pages 614-626, May.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:sae:urbstu:v:34:y:1997:i:12:p:1971-1986. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: SAGE Publications (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.gla.ac.uk/departments/urbanstudiesjournal .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.