IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/enreec/v63y2016i3p665-686.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Sharing a Fish Stock When Distribution and Harvest Costs are Density Dependent

Author

Listed:
  • Xiaozi Liu
  • Marko Lindroos
  • Leif Sandal

Abstract

We studied cooperative and competitive solutions for managing a trans-boundary fish stock that has a stock-size dependent distribution and harvesting costs, using Norwegian spring-spawning (NSS) herring (Clupea harengus) as a case study. This is among the first studies to investigate the effect of a dynamic distribution in a partition function game framework, i.e., including externalities. The special feature of NSS herring is that it comes under the sole ownership of Norway when the stock size is sufficiently low. The three players in our game are differentiated by stock ownership, cost per unit effort and stock elasticity of harvest. We find that cost asymmetry improves the likelihood of forming a stable grand coalition as harvesting load can be assigned to each fishing zone according to a player’s relative cost level and the density of fish. A dynamic distribution increases the bargaining power of Norway because of her ability to control both the total stock and the stock shares in different zones, especially during the stock transition years. However, the bargaining power of Norway may disappear if her cost of harvesting exceeds that of the other players. This loss of bargaining power can take on two forms: first, a dynamic distribution may encourage a minor player to free ride because Norway, needing a coalition partner to improve her cost-effectiveness, would be less inclined to retaliate as retaliation hurts her ally as much as the free-rider; second, in a stable grand coalition, Norway is not guaranteed to receive an allocation of benefit shares in proportion to (not to say in excess of) her stock ownership. At the current stock condition, the strategy where Norway reduces stock abundance below the level where the stock becomes non-migratory is found attractive only if the discounting rate is sufficiently high. Copyright Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2016

Suggested Citation

  • Xiaozi Liu & Marko Lindroos & Leif Sandal, 2016. "Sharing a Fish Stock When Distribution and Harvest Costs are Density Dependent," Environmental & Resource Economics, Springer;European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, vol. 63(3), pages 665-686, March.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:enreec:v:63:y:2016:i:3:p:665-686
    DOI: 10.1007/s10640-014-9858-9
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/s10640-014-9858-9
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/s10640-014-9858-9?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Saavedra–Nieves, Alejandro & Casas–Méndez, Balbina, 2023. "On the centrality analysis of covert networks using games with externalities," European Journal of Operational Research, Elsevier, vol. 309(3), pages 1365-1378.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Coalition game; Dynamic stock distribution; International resource management; Partition function game; Modified Shapley value; C71; Q22; Q57;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • C71 - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods - - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory - - - Cooperative Games
    • Q22 - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics - - Renewable Resources and Conservation - - - Fishery
    • Q57 - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics - - Environmental Economics - - - Ecological Economics

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:enreec:v:63:y:2016:i:3:p:665-686. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.