IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/jda/journl/vol.50year2016issue2pp153-183.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Trade, overeducation, and wage inequality

Author

Listed:
  • Sherif Khalifa

    (California State University, USA)

Abstract

Contrary to the predictions of the 2x2x2 Heckscher-Ohlin model, empirical evidence shows that trade openness causes the skill premium to increase in some developing countries and to decrease in others. This paper introduces a North-South setup, where the labor force is divided into skilled and unskilled workers. There are two types of firms: producers of final goods and producers of intermediate goods. There are two types of final goods: a complex good and a simple good. The former is produced utilizing skilled workers who completed their training, and a range of complex complementary intermediates. The latter is produced utilizing skilled workers who did not complete their training, unskilled workers, and a range of simple complementary intermediates. Complex and simple intermediates are produced by technology monopolists in the North, and used by producers of final goods both in the North and in the South. The results suggest that the skill premium increases in the North after trade liberalization if and only if the employment in the complex sector relative to the simple sector in the North is higher than that in the South. On the other hand, the effect of trade liberalization on the skill premium in the South depends on the level of overeducation. The skill premium is the ratio of the weighted average wage of all skilled workers to that of the unskilled workers. The wage of skilled workers is a weighted average of the wage of the skilled workers in the complex sector and in the simple sector. In the South, trade openness causes a decrease in the wage of the former and an increase in the wage of the latter. If the portion of the latter is higher than that of the former, the weighted average wage of skilled workers and the skill premium increase after trade liberalization. Otherwise, the skill premium declines. Therefore, the effect of trade liberalization on the skill premium in the South depends on the level of skill mismatch, or the portion of skilled workers in the simple sector. The empirical estimation using a threshold estimation technique provides evidence to support the theoretical findings.

Suggested Citation

  • Sherif Khalifa, 2016. "Trade, overeducation, and wage inequality," Journal of Developing Areas, Tennessee State University, College of Business, vol. 50(2), pages 153-183, April-Jun.
  • Handle: RePEc:jda:journl:vol.50:year:2016:issue2:pp:153-183
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://muse.jhu.edu/article/621341
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Dorcas Gonese & Asrat Tsegaye & Forget Kapingura & Sibanesizwe Alwyn Khumalo, 2022. "Trade Openness and Income Inequality: A Case of Southern African Development Community Countries," Eurasian Journal of Economics and Finance, Eurasian Publications, vol. 10(4), pages 135-151.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Trade liberalization; overeducation; wage inequality;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • F16 - International Economics - - Trade - - - Trade and Labor Market Interactions
    • J31 - Labor and Demographic Economics - - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs - - - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
    • O34 - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth - - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights - - - Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:jda:journl:vol.50:year:2016:issue2:pp:153-183. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Abu N.M. Wahid (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/cbtnsus.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.