IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/esj/esriea/149a.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Economic Growth and the Characteristics of Technology in Japan (in Japanese)

Author

Listed:
  • Hikaru Sakuramoto
  • Kazushige Shimpo
  • Mikio Suga
  • Naoyuki Kainuma
  • Katsumi Hirashita
  • Yoshihito Urashima
  • Hirofumi Nishu

Abstract

1 Objectives The aim of this study is to examine empirically the characteristics of economic growth in Japan for the period from 1960 to 1990, from the perspective of technological progress and the spread of productivity growth across sectors. This study is motivated by two main reasons. Firstly, it is initiated by the recent development in the 'New Growth Theory' highlighting the endogenous growth factor. The second reason lies in the need to re-examine the results of past studies using economic observations of the Japanese economy after the oil crisis. The first objective of this study is to calculate productivity growth by sector and its contributing factors using the input-output table. The second objective is to estimate the spillover effect of productivity growth from one sector to another through inter-sectoral dependency. 2 Main Characteristics of the Analysisa Triangularization of Sectors By rearranging the sectors producing intermediate inputs in the input-output table topdown from products requiring a high degree of processing (final goods) to products requiring alow degree of processing (intermediate goods, in particular basic materials), it is found that final goods are seldom used as intermediate inputs in the production of others goods. On the other hand, while intermediate goods are frequently used as inputs in the production of other goods, they are less likely to be demanded as final goods. Hence, the sectoral spillover of productivity growth tends to lie in one direction. This implies that productivity growth in products requiring a high degree of processing will have no effect on products requiring a low degree of processing, whereas productivity growth in products requiring a low degree of processing will have an effect on products requiring a high degree of processing. b Interdependency Between Products Products could be rearranged into several blocks via triangularization. A kind of block interdependency is found to exhibit through the use of intermediate inputs among the blocks. As shown in Table 5 on page 45, the 12 major product blocks could be further divided into 50 product blocks. Further, the formation of hierarchies through the structure of the intermediate goods was observed within the 12 major blocks and within the 50 smaller blocks (ordering among blocks). In addition, the ordering of products with a low degree of processing at the bottom and products with a high degree of processing at the top according to the ordering in triangularization is also observed within each block. c Measurement of the Rate of Technological Progress By defining the rate of technological progress as the growth in total factor productivity (TFP), TFP of 50 sectors are measured for the period between 1960 and 1990. 3 Resultsa Growth Characteristics of the Japanese Economyi. Capital input had the largest contribution to growth, with the rate of increase(7.6%) in capital input being greater than the rate of output increase(6.8%). ii. Labour input had a 13% contribution to growth, and an annual growth rate of 1.7%. This could be broken down into the 1.0% annual growth of labour force in man-hour base and the 0.7% annual growth rate of improvement in labour quality. iii. Technological progress recorded an average annual growth rate of 2.2%, and its contribution to growth was large at 33%. The rapid slowdown in the rate of technological progress after 1975 constituted one of the reasons for the slow economic growth. b Static Spillover Effects of Technological Progress and Productivity Growth The rate of price increase of an output from a particular sector is measured by subtracting the rate of technological progress in that sector from the product of the share of material inputs and the rate of price increase in material inputs. For instance, Rate of output price increase = Share of the respective material inputs * Rate of price increase of the respective material inputs + Share of labour input * Rate of wage increase + Share of capital input * Rate of price increase in capital. Therefore, by the above relationship, we could measure the effect of technological progress in one sector in reducing the price of output of another sector. This is termed the static spillover effect. c The Relationship Between Static Spillover Effects and Structural Changes The static spillover effect has a close relationship with structural changes in the Japanese economy via the changes in resource allocation among the various systems of basic materials. In an historical perspective, an increasing amount of resources was allocated to sectors in which there was productivity growth in the sectors themselves, and to sectors which contributed to the price reduction in product sector requiring a high degree of processing via spillover obtained through the basic materials used. For the period from 1960 to 1985, large output increases were observed in sectors with productivity increase such as ore mining (h1) and secondary energy products (I). On the other hand, stagnation was observed in sectoral blocks belonging to basic material sectors such as agricultural products (h3), fisheries (h4), livestock products (h5) and materials for natural textiles (h6), in which there had been no productivity improvements. Hence, resources were allocated from sectors with low productivity to sectors with high productivity. d Dynamic Spillover Effects of Productivity Growth The static spillover effect resulted in the price reduction in the final goods, in particular investment goods. While the price reduction in the investment goods resulted in price reduction of capital services through the static spillover effects, we termed the ultimate price reduction effect exerted on the other sectors as the dynamic spillover effects. On the other hand, the employment coefficients had decreased rapidly in all sectors while labour productivity had increased. Although the capital coefficients had decreased in a few sectors, they had increased in most other sectors. This phenomenon was in particular distinguishing during the high growth era. e Spillover Effect of the Computer Sector (b5) Sectors that had experienced continuous productivity growth were mainly found in the industrial machinery (B) block. In particular, the computer sector (b5) had recorded rapid productivity growth in recent years, and it was contributing both in static and dynamic terms to cost reduction in other sectors. The every 5-year annual productivity growth from 1960 to 1990 in the computer sector were 6.1817%, 2.1687%, 1.2742%, 6.0535%, 0.7910% and 4.5262% respectively. As for the static spillover effect, the 5-year average since 1960 were 0.0833%, 0.0431%,0.0091%, 0.0922%, 0.0447% and 0.1658% respectively. The dynamic spillover effects for the same period were 0.2725%,0.1352%,0.0294%,0.3105%,0.1618%,0.4526% respectively. For the period after 1985, differences in the static spillover effects and dynamic spillover effects had been enlarging,and the computer sector was playing an increasingly important role as a provider of investment good.

Suggested Citation

  • Hikaru Sakuramoto & Kazushige Shimpo & Mikio Suga & Naoyuki Kainuma & Katsumi Hirashita & Yoshihito Urashima & Hirofumi Nishu, 1997. "Economic Growth and the Characteristics of Technology in Japan (in Japanese)," Economic Analysis, Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI), vol. 149, pages 2-97, March.
  • Handle: RePEc:esj:esriea:149a
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://www.esri.go.jp/jp/archive/bun/bun149/bun149a.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:esj:esriea:149a. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: HORI nobuko (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/esrgvjp.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.