IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ags/pugtwp/331476.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

The welfare impacts of targeted transfers to poor households

Author

Listed:
  • McDonald, Scott
  • Pauw, Kalie

Abstract

South African researchers and policymakers have for some time now been exploring the idea of basic income grants and extended welfare transfer schemes as a means to reduce poverty and inequality in the country. Despite the fact that poverty in South Africa is widespread there is a general consensus among policymakers about the preference of targeted welfare grants over non-targeted grants due to the huge budgetary implications of the latter. Targeting, however, brings with it increased administrative complexities both with respect to means testing that is required and the challenge of successfully identifying appropriate recipients. These administrative complexities introduce a cost dimension that is as yet largely unexplored. This paper reports the results from a series of simulations that evaluate the general equilibrium and welfare implications of different schemes for targeted transfers. The poverty and inequality implications are evaluated using microsimulation techniques that link the representative households in the CGE model to the household surveys. The general equilibrium model is calibrated with an aggregation of the PROVIDE Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for South Africa for the year 2000. Distinctive features of the SAM include detailed factor and household accounts: overall the SAM has 32 commodities, 39 activities, 56 factors, including GOS (capital), nine land factors and 46 labour factors, and the 162 household accounts of the PROVIDE SAM. The labour accounts distinguish between types of labour on the basis of occupational category, race and province of residence, while the household accounts distinguish between households on the basis of race, gender and educational achievements of the ‘head’ of household; province of residence further disaggregated according to whether the district of residence was in a former homeland; and, for larger groups, the level of income. A distinctive feature of the SAM is the fact that there is a complete mapping of the individual households in the Income and Expenditure and Labour Force Surveys to the representative households in the SAM. It is this mapping that allows the development of detailed associated microsimulation techniques. The simulations assume that the total value of transfers, excluding administrative costs, is constrained at R15 billion (approximately US$2.5 billion or 2.4% of total government expenditure). The simulations explore the effectiveness of different targeting regimes, e.g., broad targeting (associated with a low per capita transfer value) versus narrow targeting (associated with a high transfer value), under the assumption that the targeting regimes are determined by reference to the characteristics of the representative household groups. For all simulations, the impact of adding an administrative cost component to the expenditure side is also explored. Various tax replacement policies are explored under alternative financing options; from a welfare point of view these are important, especially when tax rates paid by households that are close to the poverty line change. The effectiveness of different targeting schemes in reducing poverty and inequality is explored in depth. This is achieved by extracting results on per capita income changes from the general equilibrium model and feeding these into a micro-level module that calculates poverty and inequality at the individual level. The results indicate that the poverty impact of the R15 billion transfer is typically small: the poverty headcount falls from about 49% in the base to approximately 46% in the simulations. However for some household groups, which are in close proximity to the selected poverty line, poverty actually increases due to the increased tax burden. This highlights the importance of ensuring an equitable distribution of the increased tax burden. Inequality also declines marginally in all the simulations considered, mainly because poor households are targeted while non-poor households typically carry a larger share of the increased tax burden. In as far as the effectiveness of broad versus narrow targeting is concerned the results suggest that narrower targeting generally implies greater reductions in poverty and inequality, although it depends crucially on how far the recipients are located from the poverty line and the funding regime. The paper concludes with a discussion of alternative targeting regimes.

Suggested Citation

  • McDonald, Scott & Pauw, Kalie, 2006. "The welfare impacts of targeted transfers to poor households," Conference papers 331476, Purdue University, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Global Trade Analysis Project.
  • Handle: RePEc:ags:pugtwp:331476
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://ageconsearch.umn.edu/record/331476/files/2264.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Other versions of this item:

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Anthony J. Venables, 2003. "Winners and losers from regional integration agreements," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 113(490), pages 747-761, October.
    2. Puga, Diego & Venables, Anthony J, 1999. "Agglomeration and Economic Development: Import Substitution vs. Trade Liberalisation," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 109(455), pages 292-311, April.
    3. Francois, Joseph & Bradley McDonald, 1996. "Liberalization and Capital Accumulation in the GTAP Model," GTAP Technical Papers 310, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. J. Vernon Henderson, Zmarak Shalizi, and Anthony J. Venables, 2001. "Geography and development," Journal of Economic Geography, Oxford University Press, vol. 1(1), pages 81-105, January.
    2. Fugazza, Marco & Robert-Nicoud, Frédéric, 2006. "Can South-South trade Liberalisation Stimulate North-South Trade ?," Journal of Economic Integration, Center for Economic Integration, Sejong University, vol. 21, pages 234-253.
    3. Alessia Lo Turco, 2005. "South-South Trade Agreements, Location of Production and Inequality in Latin America," Ibero America Institute for Econ. Research (IAI) Discussion Papers 127, Ibero-America Institute for Economic Research.
    4. Islam, Sulequl, 2003. "Expansions of the European Union and the NAFTA: Implications for New and Non-Member countries," Applied Econometrics and International Development, Euro-American Association of Economic Development, vol. 3(2).
    5. Pedro Moncarz & Marcelo Olarreaga & Marcel Vaillant, 2016. "Regionalism as Industrial Policy: Evidence from MERCOSUR," Review of Development Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 20(1), pages 359-373, February.
    6. Sarah Ellis Barnekow & Kishore G. Kulkarni, 2017. "Why Regionalism? A Look at the Costs and Benefits of Regional Trade Agreements in Africa," Global Business Review, International Management Institute, vol. 18(1), pages 99-117, February.
    7. Higashi, Akiko, 2020. "Analysis of Japanese power supply beyond 2020 using the GTAP-E-Power model," Conference papers 333200, Purdue University, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Global Trade Analysis Project.
    8. Baldwin, Richard & Venables, Anthony J., 2015. "Trade policy and industrialisation when backward and forward linkages matter," Research in Economics, Elsevier, vol. 69(2), pages 123-131.
    9. Güneş Aşık & Ulaş Karakoç & Şevket Pamuk, 2023. "Regional inequalities and the West–East divide in Turkey since 1913," Economic History Review, Economic History Society, vol. 76(4), pages 1305-1332, November.
    10. Mr. Meredith A McIntyre, 2005. "Trade Integration in the East African Community: An Assessment for Kenya," IMF Working Papers 2005/143, International Monetary Fund.
    11. Khan, Aamir & Walmsley, Terrie & Mukhopadhyay, Kakali, 2019. "Trade Liberalization and Income Inequality: The Case for Pakistan," Conference papers 333125, Purdue University, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Global Trade Analysis Project.
    12. Thierry Mayer, 2006. "Policy Coherence for Development: A Background Paper on Foreign Direct Investment," OECD Development Centre Working Papers 253, OECD Publishing.
    13. Andrea Moro & Peter Norman, 2019. "Endogenous Comparative Advantage," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 121(3), pages 1088-1124, July.
    14. Ashok S. Guha & Brishti Guha, 2009. "Trade, Growth, and Increasing Returns to Infrastructure: The Role of the Sophisticated Monopolist," Review of International Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 17(5), pages 1053-1065, November.
    15. Jaime DE MELO & Yvonne TSIKATA, 2014. "Regional integration in Africa: Challenges and prospects," Working Papers P93, FERDI.
    16. Abbott, Philip & Bentzen, Jeanet & Huong, Thi Lan & Tarp, Finn, 2007. "A Critical Review of Studies on the Social and Economic Impacts of Vietnam’s International Economic Integration," MPRA Paper 29789, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    17. G Ottaviano & Diego Puga, 1997. "Agglomeration in a global Economy: A Survey," CEP Discussion Papers dp0356, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
    18. Boiscuvier, Éléonore, 2001. "Innovation, intégration et développement régional," L'Actualité Economique, Société Canadienne de Science Economique, vol. 77(2), pages 255-280, juin.
    19. Alice Nicole Sindzingre, 2016. "From an Eroding Model to Questioned Trade Relationships: The European Union and Sub-Saharan Africa," Insight on Africa, , vol. 8(2), pages 81-95, July.
    20. Viral V. Acharya, 2003. "Is the International Convergence of Capital Adequacy Regulation Desirable?," Journal of Finance, American Finance Association, vol. 58(6), pages 2745-2782, December.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ags:pugtwp:331476. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: AgEcon Search (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/gtpurus.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.