IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/aoq/ekonom/y2021i3p440-448.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Austrian and Mainstream Economics on Mathematics – a Comment on Pieniążek (2018): Reply to Machaj

Author

Listed:
  • Piotr Pieniążek

Abstract

Machaj’s (2019) interesting comment on my original article (Pieniążek, 2018) makes several points. The major one is that in my discussion of the usefulness of the Austrian School of Economics’ (henceforth: ASE) tool of study, which is praxeology, I have drawn a faulty conclusion about its non-usefulness. Next, he discusses the status of mathematics as a language in general and in particular its applicability to economics. Finally, he tries to give an example of an ill-suited application of mathematics to economics by considering a neoclassical production function in the context of economic growth. Before I address the content of Machaj’s remarks, I think it would add to clarity if we consider the terminology he employs. He mentions at the beginning of his comment that he prefers to use the term neoclassical economics over mainstream economics (henceforth: ME) and seems to equate the two in the remainder of the text. He does not, however, provide any reasons for this nor does he argue with the distinction of mainstream economics vis-à-vis neoclassical economics that I employed in my original article. Why does he disregard, then, the typical convention that, say, an authoritative figure in the field, Acemoglu (2009) followed in his exposition of economic growth, i.e. the very topic that Machaj uses as an example of economics in his comment? Acemoglu divided the models he analyzed into the neoclassical group and the rest, despite the fact that both of the groups are undoubtedly mainstream, which suggests that the two terms are not equivalent. Although I did not elaborate deeply on the issue in my original article, I was sticking to the spirit of Colander (2000), who argued for the terminasia of neoclassical economics, i.e. for the economist-assisted killing of a term whose use is inconsistent and whose content is difficult to determine, typically being so ambiguous that it renders the term almost meaningless. It should not surprise us, as since 1900 up to the present, it has meant to describe very different ways of doing economics since the 1840s up to the present; however, the discipline has experienced such an enormous change since the 1840s (now even greater than at the time when Colander wrote his paper) that it could not possibly mean the same thing as even a century ago, rendering the term a very imprecise and hence misleading category. Moreover, even McCloskey (2010, pp. 8, 414) that Machaj mentions twice in his comment, classified Mengerian (i.e. the ASE’s) economics as neoclassical1. Given that Machaj himself juxtaposes the neoclassical with the ASE’s economics, it creates an even greater classificational mess. For all of these reasons, I prefer to terminate (nomen est omen) using the term neoclassical economics in the current context and, following my original article, stick to the mainstream economics category when denoting the economics that is contemporarily being practiced in the top journals and at the top universities. Having in mind this terminological remark, I am ready to address Machaj’s major objections to my original article.

Suggested Citation

  • Piotr Pieniążek, 2021. "Austrian and Mainstream Economics on Mathematics – a Comment on Pieniążek (2018): Reply to Machaj," Ekonomista, Polskie Towarzystwo Ekonomiczne, issue 3, pages 440-448.
  • Handle: RePEc:aoq:ekonom:y:2021:i:3:p:440-448
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://ekonomista.pte.pl/pdf-150133-75854
    File Function: Full text
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Oded Galor, 2011. "Unified Growth Theory," Economics Books, Princeton University Press, edition 1, number 9477.
    2. Oded Galor, 2011. "Unified Growth Theory and Comparative Development," Rivista di Politica Economica, SIPI Spa, issue 2, pages 9-21, April-Jun.
    3. Lucas, Robert Jr., 1988. "On the mechanics of economic development," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 22(1), pages 3-42, July.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Kawalec Paweł, 2020. "The dynamics of theories of economic growth: An impact of Unified Growth Theory," Economics and Business Review, Sciendo, vol. 6(2), pages 19-44, June.
    2. James Foreman-Peck & Peng Zhou, 2021. "Fertility versus productivity: a model of growth with evolutionary equilibria," Journal of Population Economics, Springer;European Society for Population Economics, vol. 34(3), pages 1073-1104, July.
    3. Altinok, Nadir & Aydemir, Abdurrahman, 2017. "Does one size fit all? The impact of cognitive skills on economic growth," Journal of Macroeconomics, Elsevier, vol. 53(C), pages 176-190.
    4. Bloom, David E. & Canning, David & Kotschy, Rainer & Prettner, Klaus & Schünemann, Johannes, 2024. "Health and economic growth: Reconciling the micro and macro evidence," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 178(C).
    5. Schäfer, Andreas & Prettner, Klaus, 2016. "The fall and rise of inequality," VfS Annual Conference 2016 (Augsburg): Demographic Change 145806, Verein für Socialpolitik / German Economic Association.
    6. Oscar Hernán Cerquera Losada & María de los Ángeles Clavijo Tovar & Carla Yanella Pérez Peña, 2022. "Capital humano y crecimiento económico: evidencia empírica para Suramérica," Apuntes del Cenes, Universidad Pedagógica y Tecnológica de Colombia, vol. 41(73), pages 143-167, February.
    7. Matteo Cervellati & Uwe Sunde & Klaus F. Zimmermann, 2017. "Demographic dynamics and long-run development: insights for the secular stagnation debate," Journal of Population Economics, Springer;European Society for Population Economics, vol. 30(2), pages 401-432, April.
    8. Madsen, Jakob B. & Raschky, Paul A. & Skali, Ahmed, 2015. "Does democracy drive income in the world, 1500–2000?," European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 78(C), pages 175-195.
    9. Claude Diebolt & Faustine Perrin, 2019. "A Cliometric Model of Unified Growth: Family Organization and Economic Growth in the Long Run of History," Studies in Economic History, in: Claude Diebolt & Auke Rijpma & Sarah Carmichael & Selin Dilli & Charlotte Störmer (ed.), Cliometrics of the Family, chapter 0, pages 7-31, Springer.
    10. Gabriele Cappelli & Michelangelo Vasta, 2021. "A “Silent Revolution”: school reforms and Italy’s educational gender gap in the Liberal Age (1861–1921)," Cliometrica, Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History, Association Française de Cliométrie (AFC), vol. 15(1), pages 203-229, January.
    11. David E. Bloom & Michael Kuhn & Klaus Prettner, 2022. "Modern Infectious Diseases: Macroeconomic Impacts and Policy Responses," Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 60(1), pages 85-131, March.
    12. Michał Burzyński & Christoph Deuster & Frédéric Docquier & Jaime de Melo, 2022. "Climate Change, Inequality, and Human Migration," Journal of the European Economic Association, European Economic Association, vol. 20(3), pages 1145-1197.
    13. Victor Court & Pierre-André Jouvet & Frédéric Lantz, 2018. "Long-term endogenous economic growth and energy transitions," The Energy Journal, International Association for Energy Economics, vol. 0(Number 1).
    14. Antony, Jürgen & Klarl, Torben, 2022. "Poverty and sustainable development around the world during transition periods," Energy Economics, Elsevier, vol. 110(C).
    15. David E. Bloom & Alex Khoury & Vadim Kufenko & Klaus Prettner, 2021. "Spurring Economic Growth through Human Development: Research Results and Guidance for Policymakers," Population and Development Review, The Population Council, Inc., vol. 47(2), pages 377-409, June.
    16. Das, Gouranga G. & Drine, Imed, 2020. "Distance from the technology frontier: How could Africa catch-up via socio-institutional factors and human capital?," Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Elsevier, vol. 150(C).
    17. Kaldewei, Cornelia & Weller, Jürgen, 2013. "Empleo, crecimiento sostenible e igualdad," Macroeconomía del Desarrollo 35881, Naciones Unidas Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL).
    18. Jakob Brochner Madsen, 2016. "Human Accomplishment and Growth in Britain since 1270: The Role of Great Scientists and Education," Monash Economics Working Papers 01-16, Monash University, Department of Economics.
    19. Guo, Rongxing & Yang, Kaizhong & Liu, Yuhui, 2020. "Explaining the human and cultural puzzles: A new development theory✰," Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Elsevier, vol. 155(C).
    20. Sivropoulos-Valero, Anna Alexandra, 2021. "Education and economic growth," LSE Research Online Documents on Economics 114434, London School of Economics and Political Science, LSE Library.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    review;

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:aoq:ekonom:y:2021:i:3:p:440-448. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Tomasz Kwarcinski (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/pteeeea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.