IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ohe/monogr/000461.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Narrowing the Gap between provision and need for medicines in developing countries

Author

Listed:
  • Hannah Kettler

Abstract

Health and economic development is positively linked. External investments are needed to break the vicious cycle of poor health and poverty plaguing less developed countries (LDCs). Measured in disability adjusted life years (DALYs), the disease burden suffered per person in LDCs is twice that of people in established market economies (EMEs). The two regions also have distinct disease patterns with almost 40 percent of LDCs’ healthy years lost to communicable, maternal, and prenatal diseases as opposed to only 8 percent in EMEs. The size and pattern of disease burden in LDCs are linked to wider problems of inadequate infrastructure in education, sanitation, transportation, and so on. These infrastructure problems, together with lack of money, prevent populations from using many existing treatments effectively. In many disease areas, however, effective treatments simply do not exist. Here, investments in new research and development (R&D) are critical. Diarrhoeal diseases, malaria, tuberculosis, and respiratory infections are among the top global 12 disease categories but they occur almost exclusively in LDCs and are therefore not a priority for the investors in pharmaceutical R&D. In 1992, of the $55.8 billion invested in health care world-wide, only an estimated $2.4 billion or 4 percent were allocated towards LDC diseases. In sharp contrast to health care research in general, where the pharmaceutical industry and EME governments are the primary investors, official development assistance organizations and LDC governments paid for two thirds of the small amount of money spent on R&D for LDC issues. The political challenge, therefore, is to make LDC health concerns a greater priority of EME R&D investors, as this is where the funding and the experience are centred. R&D investment priorities are a function of market size, the degree of current and future need and the probability of success (a function of the state of science, in-house resources and experience and risk). As the expected number of patients able to pay for medicines is small, LDC-diseases tend not to be prioritised, and this is despite the significant need for new products in these countries. The public sectors of the EMEs can intervene in two ways to try and correct these market failures. First, they can improve ‘push’ and ‘pull’ incentives to try and make it more attractive for private companies to invest in these disease markets. I call this the ‘commercial assistance’ approach. Second, they can provide direct public funding for research and product development in these areas. Teams of academic and industry scientists from both developed and developing regions could compete for this funding. I refer to this as the ‘public-based’ approach. It is a challenge to identify policies that will: 1) incentivize companies to invest; 2) be acceptable to EME governments (i.e. policies which they will be willing and able to legislate and fund); and 3) produce medicines that the LDCs are able to afford. Also at issue is how to formulate a package of policies that will encourage both ‘local’ (LDC) and multinational participants. To motivate private companies, in a ‘commercial assistance’ approach, a package of incentives, rather than one single remedy, would work best to incentivize both small and large companies and bring public and private resources together. A modified orphan drug policy that puts together R&D tax credits and grants with a significant pull measure might shift the cost-revenue balance of LDC diseases. From the standpoint of large companies, this pull incentive must be significant and the promise of funds be credible. Companies are likely to find a roaming exclusivity clause or a guaranteed purchase fund attractive. A roaming exclusivity clause would permit companies to extend market exclusivity for any of their approved products in exchange for marketing an approved LDC drug at affordable prices. A guaranteed purchase fund, such as that proposed by Jeffrey Sachs and Michael Kremer for malaria, TB, and HIV vaccines, would provide companies with the assurance that if their R&D were successful, then there would be a market for their product. Given that it takes many years to develop a patentable idea into a marketable product, the effectiveness of any incentive depends on assurance that funders will uphold promises made now in the future. Following along another, ‘public based’ parallel track, public money could be used to set up LDC-disease focused research units or to finance competitions for proposals from academic and industry researchers to conduct the necessary research at their respective facilities. The new Medicines for Malaria Venture (MMV) is an example of the latter. Industry participates in these public based ventures contributing in-kind resources such as technologies or experience, especially in the clinical trial stages. Financial rewards from these contributions are not expected, at least in the short to medium term, though companies do stand to be benefit from the positive public relations, networking opportunities, and shared access to new, scientific breakthroughs. The two approaches (commercial assisted and public based) are not mutually exclusive. Market based incentives for companies may be more effective for certain diseases than others. Differences between diseases in the size of the potential ‘market’ (i.e. prevalence in LDCs), the state of the science and the type of companies involved (i.e. small biotechnology companies, large multinational pharmaceutical companies) may mean different combinations of incentives are needed. In cases where researchers still do not understand the science, the promise of markets some time in the future may do little to motivate investment. In other cases, developed, patentable ideas may have been shelved because of the lack of a viable market. From the standpoint of the patients in LDCs, most critical is that the products are affordable and accessible, which raises the importance of combining incentives for research with efforts to improve access infrastructure and deal, in advance, with pricing questions. Ultimately, the greatest challenge may be that of how to get the players involved to back verbal commitments with money and resources. EME governments, for example, must convince a complex set of interest groups to agree to make LDC-diseases a priority for any of the above approaches to work. It may be harder to convince the US or UK taxpayer than a large multinational pharmaceutical company that investments in LDC-diseases are worthwhile. The potential for real action is there. A number of teams with representatives from industry, international aid and activist organizations and academics are currently working to come up with viable alternatives to attract new investments. In order to put their ideas into practice, these groups must move fast to involve all relevant players, especially payers, in the negotiations.

Suggested Citation

  • Hannah Kettler, 2000. "Narrowing the Gap between provision and need for medicines in developing countries," Monograph 000461, Office of Health Economics.
  • Handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000461
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://www.ohe.org/publications/narrowing-gap-between-provision-and-need-medicines-developing-countries/attachment-264-2000_narrowing_the_gap_kettler/
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. DiMasi, Joseph A. & Hansen, Ronald W. & Grabowski, Henry G. & Lasagna, Louis, 1991. "Cost of innovation in the pharmaceutical industry," Journal of Health Economics, Elsevier, vol. 10(2), pages 107-142, July.
    2. Mansfield, Edwin, 1991. "Academic research and industrial innovation," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 20(1), pages 1-12, February.
    3. Renee Prendergast & Frances Stewart (ed.), 1994. "Market Forces and World Development," Palgrave Macmillan Books, Palgrave Macmillan, number 978-1-349-23138-6.
    4. Hannah Kettler, 1998. "Competition through Innovation, Innovation through Competition," Monograph 000434, Office of Health Economics.
    5. David Taylor, 1982. "Medicines, Health and the Poor World," Series on Health 000331, Office of Health Economics.
    6. Hannah Kettler, 1999. "Updating the Cost of a New Chemical Entity," Monograph 000456, Office of Health Economics.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Daems, Rutger & Maes, Edith & Ramani, Shyama V., 2011. "Global Framework for Differential Pricing of Pharmaceuticals," MERIT Working Papers 2011-054, United Nations University - Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (MERIT).
    2. Farasat A.S. Bokhari & Franco Mariuzzo & Weijie Yan, 2019. "Antibacterial resistance and the cost of affecting demand: the case of UK antibiotics," Working Paper series, University of East Anglia, Centre for Competition Policy (CCP) 2019-03, Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia, Norwich, UK..

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Toole, Andrew A., 2012. "The impact of public basic research on industrial innovation: Evidence from the pharmaceutical industry," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 41(1), pages 1-12.
    2. Hannah Kettler, 2001. "Consolidation and Competition in the Pharmaceutical Industry," Monograph 000468, Office of Health Economics.
    3. Toole, Andrew A., 2011. "The impact of public basic research on industrial innovation: Evidence from the pharmaceutical industry," ZEW Discussion Papers 11-063, ZEW - Leibniz Centre for European Economic Research.
    4. Steven Casper;Hannah Kettler, 2000. "The Road to Sustainability in the UK and German Biotechnology Industries," Monograph 000466, Office of Health Economics.
    5. Wipo, 2011. "World Intellectual Property Report 2011- The Changing Face of Innovation," WIPO Economics & Statistics Series, World Intellectual Property Organization - Economics and Statistics Division, number 2011:944, April.
    6. Subhra Saha & Joseph Staudt & Bruce Weinbergx, 2017. "Estimating the Local Productivity Spillovers from Science," Working Papers 17-56, Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Census Bureau.
    7. Yi-Min Chen, 2008. "How Much Does Country Matter?," International Regional Science Review, , vol. 31(4), pages 404-435, October.
    8. David Grosse Kathoefer & Jens Leker, 2012. "Knowledge transfer in academia: an exploratory study on the Not-Invented-Here Syndrome," The Journal of Technology Transfer, Springer, vol. 37(5), pages 658-675, October.
    9. Federico Caviggioli & Alessandra Colombelli & Antonio De Marco & Giuseppe Scellato & Elisa Ughetto, 2023. "Co-evolution patterns of university patenting and technological specialization in European regions," The Journal of Technology Transfer, Springer, vol. 48(1), pages 216-239, February.
    10. Grandi, Alessandro & Grimaldi, Rosa, 2005. "Academics' organizational characteristics and the generation of successful business ideas," Journal of Business Venturing, Elsevier, vol. 20(6), pages 821-845, November.
    11. Cassiman, Bruno & Veugelers, Reinhilde & Zuniga, Pluvia, 2009. "Diversity of science linkages and innovation performance: some empirical evidence from Flemish firms," Economics Discussion Papers 2009-30, Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW Kiel).
    12. Aschhoff, Birgit & Sofka, Wolfgang, 2008. "Successful Patterns of Scientific Knowledge Sourcing: Mix and Match," ZEW Discussion Papers 08-033 [rev.], ZEW - Leibniz Centre for European Economic Research.
    13. R. J. W. Tussen & R. K. Buter & Th. N. van Leeuwen, 2000. "Technological Relevance of Science: An Assessment of Citation Linkages between Patents and Research Papers," Scientometrics, Springer;Akadémiai Kiadó, vol. 47(2), pages 389-412, February.
    14. Blind, Knut & Grupp, Hariolf, 1999. "Interdependencies between the science and technology infrastructure and innovation activities in German regions: empirical findings and policy consequences," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 28(5), pages 451-468, June.
    15. Watzinger, Martin & Schnitzer, Monika, 2019. "Standing on the Shoulders of Science," Rationality and Competition Discussion Paper Series 215, CRC TRR 190 Rationality and Competition.
    16. Bronwyn H. Hall & Albert N. Link & John T. Scott, 2003. "Universities as Research Partners," The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 85(2), pages 485-491, May.
    17. Schwartz, Eduardo S., 2002. "Patents and R& D as Real Options," University of California at Los Angeles, Anderson Graduate School of Management qt86b1n43k, Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA.
    18. Gersbach, Hans & Sorger, Gerhard & Amon, Christian, 2018. "Hierarchical growth: Basic and applied research," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Elsevier, vol. 90(C), pages 434-459.
    19. Luiz Andrade & Catherine Sermet & Sylvain Pichetti, 2016. "Entry time effects and follow-on drug competition," The European Journal of Health Economics, Springer;Deutsche Gesellschaft für Gesundheitsökonomie (DGGÖ), vol. 17(1), pages 45-60, January.
    20. Luengo, María Jesús & Obeso, María, 2013. "Efeito da hélice tríplice em desempenho de inovação," RAE - Revista de Administração de Empresas, FGV-EAESP Escola de Administração de Empresas de São Paulo (Brazil), vol. 53(4), July.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Narrowing the Gap between provision and need for medicines in developing countries;

    JEL classification:

    • I1 - Health, Education, and Welfare - - Health

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ohe:monogr:000461. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Publications Manager (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ohecouk.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.