IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/ecm/nasm04/275.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Media Mergers and the Ideological Content of Programming

Author

Listed:
  • Abraham L. Wickelgren
  • David J. Balan
  • Patrick DeGraba

Abstract

This paper shows how rules restricting common ownership of multiple media outlets affect both the magnitude and diversity of the ideological content of programming. While in most industries the assumption that firms maximize profits is quite reasonable, we assume that media owners derive utility from the ideological content of programming (say, because they want to influence public policy) as well as from profit. As a result, owners are willing to sacrifice some profits to engage in their preferred form of ideological persuasion. In our model, there are two media outlets and three media owners, each of whom can have one of two ideologies. We define a parameter lÎ[-1,1] that captures the affinity between the two ideologies. If l=1 the ideologies are identical; if l=0, they are unrelated; and if l=-1, they are diametrically opposed. We find that even if common ownership is prohibited, ideological diversity is not guaranteed: if the two ideologies are sufficiently opposed (l sufficiently negative), then the owners of the two media outlets will have the same ideology. If the two ideologies are not so far apart (l positive or not too negative), however, then prohibiting common ownership will lead to ideological diversity (the owners of the two outlets will have different ideologies). When there is ideological diversity, the total magnitude of ideological content is greater since we assume diminishing returns to ideological persuasion. By the same token, the greater the ideological diversity, the greater is the total magnitude of ideological content. If common ownership is permitted, we find that common ownership often eliminates the ideological diversity that would have existed if the two ideologies were not too opposed (l positive or not too negative). On the other hand, if the two ideologies are strongly opposed, then allowing for common ownership can lead to diversity that would not have otherwise existed. The reason is that an owner of both outlets puts more ideological content into her programming at each outlet than would two different owners who are ideologically similar. (Some of the viewers lost when programming becomes more ideological switch to the other outlet; an owner of both outlets internalizes this externality.) This raises the cost of not owning at least one outlet for the potential owner whose ideology is very opposed to the ideology of the first owner. This increases her willingness to pay for the second outlet if she believes the alternative is common ownership. There is also another equilibrium where the owner with the opposed ideology believes that the alternative to her owning the second outlet is separate ownership by owners with identical ideologies. In this equilibrium, permitting common ownership does not lead to more ideological diversity. The issues of the ideological diversity of the media and the amount of ideological programming have a myriad of important implications. In particular, both of these issues have significant effects on how the media influences government policy.

Suggested Citation

  • Abraham L. Wickelgren & David J. Balan & Patrick DeGraba, 2004. "Media Mergers and the Ideological Content of Programming," Econometric Society 2004 North American Summer Meetings 275, Econometric Society.
  • Handle: RePEc:ecm:nasm04:275
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    To our knowledge, this item is not available for download. To find whether it is available, there are three options:
    1. Check below whether another version of this item is available online.
    2. Check on the provider's web page whether it is in fact available.
    3. Perform a search for a similarly titled item that would be available.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Media; Mergers; Media Cross Ownership;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • L41 - Industrial Organization - - Antitrust Issues and Policies - - - Monopolization; Horizontal Anticompetitive Practices
    • L50 - Industrial Organization - - Regulation and Industrial Policy - - - General

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ecm:nasm04:275. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Christopher F. Baum (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/essssea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.