IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/ids/ijdsrm/v2y2010i1-2p85-97.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Risk, price, and reimbursement

Author

Listed:
  • Kjell Hausken

Abstract

The article offers five hypotheses for the inverse relationship between risk and price in terms of first and second derivatives, establishing ranges of convexity, linearity, concavity. Negative price means reimbursement. Examples of risks are malfunction of a product or service, finite loss, severe injury, death, due to a variety of causes. For products with a probability of malfunction (risk) the relationship is empirically shown to be convex in a risk versus price diagram when paying for the product, and concave when enjoying reimbursement. This also holds for ticket prices for travel with a probability of death (risk), with transition from convexity to concavity for very low risk levels. The convexity result for probability of death stands in contrast to Viscusi and Zeckhauser's (2003) finding of a linear relationship. The value of life is estimated to be $1.02 × 109 by comparing subjects' willingness to pay for risky travel, and is estimated to be $2.08 × 109 based on subjects' requiring reimbursement $108 to accept travel with death probability 4.8%. These values of life are larger than those usually reported in the literature. A possible reason may be that young students may be reluctant to place a value on life, and thus request an uncommonly large monetary amount to accept a small probability of death.

Suggested Citation

  • Kjell Hausken, 2010. "Risk, price, and reimbursement," International Journal of Decision Sciences, Risk and Management, Inderscience Enterprises Ltd, vol. 2(1/2), pages 85-97.
  • Handle: RePEc:ids:ijdsrm:v:2:y:2010:i:1/2:p:85-97
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://www.inderscience.com/link.php?id=34673
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:ids:ijdsrm:v:2:y:2010:i:1/2:p:85-97. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sarah Parker (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.inderscience.com/browse/index.php?journalID=254 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.