IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/jacrfn/v21y2009i1p90-95.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Thinking Like Adam Smith

Author

Listed:
  • Jerry Z. Muller

Abstract

This article aims to correct a number of popular misconceptions about the man who wrote The Theory of Moral Sentiments as well as The Wealth of Nations—notably, that the unfettered pursuit of self‐interest and personal liberty is a reliable prescription for prosperity, and that regulatory constraints on market forces are unnecessary or unimportant. Viewed in its entirety, Smith's work is seen as a lifelong attempt to design social institutions— government agencies as well as families, churches, schools, and joint‐stock companies—so as to harness “destructive passions” and channel self‐interest in ways that lead to the greatest public good. Although the workings of the market are viewed as the main engine of prosperity, one of Smith's purposes in writing The Wealth of Nations was to encourage politicians to resist the pressures of economic groups attempting to use political power to advance their own interests. And Smith himself is described as pursuing a “program of cultivating men of public spirit who would be moved to participate in government”—men who, armed with Smith's science of political economy, would recognize not only the role of markets in securing the greatest public good, but also the importance of an extensive framework of public services to allow markets to function effectively.

Suggested Citation

  • Jerry Z. Muller, 2009. "Thinking Like Adam Smith," Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Morgan Stanley, vol. 21(1), pages 90-95, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:bla:jacrfn:v:21:y:2009:i:1:p:90-95
    DOI: 10.1111/j.1745-6622.2009.00220.x
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-6622.2009.00220.x
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1111/j.1745-6622.2009.00220.x?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:bla:jacrfn:v:21:y:2009:i:1:p:90-95. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Wiley Content Delivery (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.blackwellpublishing.com/journal.asp?ref=1078-1196 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.