Advanced Search
MyIDEAS: Login to save this paper or follow this series

Security Needs and the Performance of the Defense Industry

Contents:

Author Info

  • Andreas Blume
  • Asher Tishler

Abstract

Today, leading defense firms are concentrated into just two distinct blocs - those based in the US and those in Western Europe. All US defense firms and most European ones are private. Market structure may thus play an important role in determining procurement levels as well as defense policies in the US and Europe. This paper focuses on the interactions between defense needs and market structure. It presents a model in which two producer blocs (representing the US and Europe) produce an identical homogeneous defense good. The "rest of the world" purchases the defense good from the two producer countries. The security level of each of the two producing countries depends on its purchase of the defense good relative to the amount of defense good purchased by the rest of the world. Each country measures its security level against a target that it sets for itself. The main results of this paper are: (1) Generally, the total world quantity of the defense good is lower when the governments of the producers of the defense good pay the world price (rather than the marginal production cost plus a markup) to their defense industries. (2) The net defense cost (government expenditure on the defense good minus the profit of the defense industry) of each producing country is lower when producing-country governments pay the world price to their own defense industries. (3) Government expenditure on the defense good and the net defense cost for each producing-country are smaller when the number of defense firms in each country is relatively small. (4) Target security levels affect the optimal number of firms in each of the two producing countries. Higher target security levels result in a larger number of defense firms. (5) Multiple equilibria in the game where the developed countries independently choose their own procurement rules are possible. ZUSAMMENFASSUNG - (Sicherheitsbedürfnisse und die Leistungsfähigkeit der Rüstungsindustrie) Heute sind die führenden Rüstungsunternehmen in zwei unterschiedlichen Regionen konzentriert: in den USA und in Westeuropa. Alle US-Unternehmen und die meisten europäischen Unternehmen sind in Privatbesitz. Insofern kann die Marktstruktur als wichtige Einflußgröße des Beschaffungsniveaus und der Verteidigungspolitik in den USA und Europa angesehen werden. Der Beitrag konzentriert sich auf die Interaktion zwischen Verteidigungsbedürfnissen und Marktstruktur. Es wird ein Modell vorgestellt, in dem zwei "Produzentenblöcke" (die USA und Europa) ein identisches, homogenes Rüstungsgut produzieren. Der "Rest der Welt" kauft das Rüstungsgut von den beiden Herstellerländern. Das Sicherheitsniveau jedes der beiden Länder hängt von dem eigenen Beschaffungsvolumen des Rüstungsguts im Vergleich zum Beschaffungsvolumen des Rüstungsguts durch den Rest der Welt ab. Jedes Land bestimmt sein Sicherheitsniveau in dem es dies mit einem selbstgesteckten Ziel vergleicht. Das Hauptergebnis besagt: (1) Im allgemeinen ist das weltweite Gesamtvolumen an Rüstungsgütern niedriger, wenn die Regierung der Herstellerländer der Rüstungsgüter den Weltmarktpreis an ihre Industrien zahlen (im Unterschied zu einer Preisbildung nach Grenzkosten der Produktion plus Zuschlag). (2) Die Nettoverteidigungsausgaben (staatliche Ausgaben für Rüstungsgüter minus der Gewinne der Rüstungsindustrie) eines jeden Herstellerlandes sind geringer, wenn die Herstellerländer den Weltmarktpreis an ihre eigene Industrie zahlen. (3) Die Staatsausgaben für die Rüstungsgüter und die Nettoverteidigungsausgaben für jedes Herstellerland sind geringer, wenn die Anzahl an Rüstungsunternehmen in jedem Land verhältnismäßig gering ist. (4) Die Höhe des gewünschten Sicherheitsniveaus beeinflußt die optimale Anzahl von Unternehmen in jedem der beiden Herstellerländer. Höhere Sicherheitsniveaus führen zu einer höheren Anzahl an Rüstungsunternehmen. (5) Multiple Gleichgewichte des Spiels, in dem die entwickelten Länder unabhängig voneinander ihre Beschaffungsregeln entscheiden, sind möglich.

Download Info

If you experience problems downloading a file, check if you have the proper application to view it first. In case of further problems read the IDEAS help page. Note that these files are not on the IDEAS site. Please be patient as the files may be large.
File URL: http://skylla.wz-berlin.de/pdf/2000/iv00-04.pdf
Download Restriction: no

Bibliographic Info

Paper provided by Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin (WZB), Research Unit: Competition and Innovation (CIG) in its series CIG Working Papers with number FS IV 00-04.

as in new window
Length: 60 pages
Date of creation: Mar 2000
Date of revision:
Handle: RePEc:wzb:wzebiv:fsiv00-04

Contact details of provider:
Postal: Reichpietschufer 50, 10785 Berlin, Germany
Phone: (++49)(30) 25491-441
Fax: (++49)(30) 25491-442
Email:
Web page: http://www.wzb.eu/mp/wiw/default.en.htm
More information through EDIRC

Related research

Keywords: Defense Industry; Technology; Security Level; Market Structure;

References

References listed on IDEAS
Please report citation or reference errors to , or , if you are the registered author of the cited work, log in to your RePEc Author Service profile, click on "citations" and make appropriate adjustments.:
as in new window
  1. D Leahy & J.P. Neary, 1995. "Public Policy Towards R&D in Oligopolistic Industries," CEP Discussion Papers dp0270, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
  2. Austan Goolsbee, 1998. "Does Government R&D Policy Mainly Benefit Scientists and Engineers?," NBER Working Papers 6532, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
  3. Rogerson, William P, 1990. "Quality vs. Quantity in Military Procurement," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 80(1), pages 83-92, March.
  4. William P. Rogerson, 1994. "Economic Incentives and the Defense Procurement Process," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 8(4), pages 65-90, Fall.
  5. William E. Kovacic & Dennis E. Smallwood, 1994. "Competition Policy, Rivalries, and Defense Industry Consolidation," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 8(4), pages 91-110, Fall.
  6. Ham, Rose Marie & Mowery, David C., 1998. "Improving the effectiveness of public-private R&D collaboration: case studies at a US weapons laboratory," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 26(6), pages 661-675, February.
  7. David M. Kreps & Jose A. Scheinkman, 1983. "Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes," Bell Journal of Economics, The RAND Corporation, vol. 14(2), pages 326-337, Autumn.
  8. Romer, Paul M, 1990. "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 98(5), pages S71-102, October.
  9. Segerstrom, Paul S, 1998. "Endogenous Growth without Scale Effects," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 88(5), pages 1290-1310, December.
  10. Dvir, D. & Lipovetsky, S. & Shenhar, A. & Tishler, A., 1998. "In search of project classification: a non-universal approach to project success factors," Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 27(9), pages 915-935, December.
Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

Citations

Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
as in new window

Cited by:
  1. Benny Mantin & Asher Tishler, 2004. "The structure of the defense industry and the security needs of the country: a differentiated products model," Defence and Peace Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 15(5), pages 397-419.

Lists

This item is not listed on Wikipedia, on a reading list or among the top items on IDEAS.

Statistics

Access and download statistics

Corrections

When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:wzb:wzebiv:fsiv00-04. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: (Jennifer Rontganger).

If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

If references are entirely missing, you can add them using this form.

If the full references list an item that is present in RePEc, but the system did not link to it, you can help with this form.

If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.