Advanced Search
MyIDEAS: Login to save this paper or follow this series

First Order Approach for Principal-Agent Models with Hidden Borrowing and Lending: The Two Period Case

Contents:

Author Info

  • Nicola Pavoni
  • Arphad Abraham

Abstract

In this paper we provide sufficient conditions for the validity of the first-order condition approach (FOCA) for two period dynamic moral hazard problems where the agent can save and borrow secretly, and we characterize the optimal contract. Recently, dynamic principal-agent models became very popular instruments to study several diverse issues such as design of optimal social insurance schemes (e.g. unemployment insurance, disability insurance), bank-firm financing relationships or efficient compensation contracts. Most of these models assume that the agent's consumption-savings decision is observable (and contractible) by the principal. However, it is also well known that this assumption is potentially very dangerous, because if the agent had a hidden opportunity to save then he would deviate from the optimal contract by doing so. Therefore, the opportunity of hidden savings will lead to a different optimal contract (Rogerson, 1985a). Moreover, in most of the above-mentioned examples, the possibility of non-contractible borrowing and lending seems to be empirically relevant. Since the seminal works of Mirrlees (1972) and Holmstrom (1979) it became clear that the study of the moral hazard models is much easier if one can rely on the FOCA. Obviously, this is even more true in a dynamic environment where the agent has secret access to the credit market. Rogerson (1985b) and Jewitt (1988) provide conditions for the validity of the FOCA in the static principal-agent model. The strategy consists of showing that in the optimal contract the agent problem is concave hence the first order conditions are actually sufficient for the optimality of the agent's effort decisions. It is not known under what conditions the FOCA can be applied to multi-period principal-agent problems with hidden asset accumulation. In fact, Kocherlakota (2003) finds that under some conditions (linearity of the effort cost and effort effectiveness), the agent problem is not concave in the optimum. In this paper, we provide sufficient conditions under which the agent's problem is concave and therefore the incentive compatibility constraints for effort and asset decisions can be replaced by their necessary and sufficient first-order conditions. We show that within the class of non-increasing absolute risk aversion (NIARA) utility functions in consumption, a simple, strongly concave, version of the spanning condition of Grossman and Hart (1983) guarantees that the agent's problem is globally concave. Our conditions imply that most of the utility functions and many effort specifications used in applications allow for a first-order-condition representation of the problem. The use of first-order conditions enables us to characterize the optimal contract in great detail. First, we show that under the assumptions needed for the FOCA the optimal consumption is monotonic in output. Then, we characterize the optimal contract further and analyze the progressivity of the optimal payment scheme. It turns out that CARA utilities with concave likelihood ratios lead to progressive schemes, that is the higher the agent's output the bigger part is taken by the principal. On the other hand, convex likelihood ratios with CRRA utilities with risk aversion larger or equal than one induce regressive schemes. In the case of log utility, this result is in sharp contrast with the case where asset holdings are observable, because there the optimal contract induces proportional schemes. In general, the possibility of hidden savings will induce more regressive optimal payment schemes compared to the observable asset accumulation case. Unfortunately, our analytical results for the two-period model cannot be easily extended for a framework with more than two periods. In another work (Abraham and Pavoni, 2004) we show that in a general multiperiod setting the FOCA is crucial to get a tractable recursive reformulation of the original problem. There, we then verify the validity of the FOCA approach ex post, numerically. Finally, note that Williams (2003) also gives sufficient conditions for the validity of the FOCA but for a different set of continuous time principal-agents models. It is not clear how his conditions map in a more standard discrete time moral hazard framework.

Download Info

To our knowledge, this item is not available for download. To find whether it is available, there are three options:
1. Check below under "Related research" whether another version of this item is available online.
2. Check on the provider's web page whether it is in fact available.
3. Perform a search for a similarly titled item that would be available.

Bibliographic Info

Paper provided by Society for Economic Dynamics in its series 2004 Meeting Papers with number 572.

as in new window
Length:
Date of creation: 2004
Date of revision:
Handle: RePEc:red:sed004:572

Contact details of provider:
Postal: Society for Economic Dynamics Christian Zimmermann Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis PO Box 442 St. Louis MO 63166-0442 USA
Fax: 1-314-444-8731
Email:
Web page: http://www.EconomicDynamics.org/society.htm
More information through EDIRC

Related research

Keywords: Dynamic Moral Hazard; First Order Approach; Hidden Assets;

Find related papers by JEL classification:

References

No references listed on IDEAS
You can help add them by filling out this form.

Citations

Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
as in new window

Cited by:
  1. Abraham, Arpad & Koehne, Sebastian & Pavoni, Nicola, 2012. "Optimal income taxation with asset accumulation," MPRA Paper 38629, University Library of Munich, Germany.
  2. Arpad Abraham & Nicola Pavoni, 2008. "Efficient Allocations with Moral Hazard and Hidden Borrowing and Lending: A Recursive Formulation," Review of Economic Dynamics, Elsevier for the Society for Economic Dynamics, vol. 11(4), pages 781-803, October.

Lists

This item is not listed on Wikipedia, on a reading list or among the top items on IDEAS.

Statistics

Access and download statistics

Corrections

When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:red:sed004:572. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: (Christian Zimmermann).

If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

If references are entirely missing, you can add them using this form.

If the full references list an item that is present in RePEc, but the system did not link to it, you can help with this form.

If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.