IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/hop/hopeec/v38y2006i5p48-85.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Complementarity and Demand Theory: From the 1920s to the 1940s

Author

Listed:
  • Jean-Sébastien Lenfant

Abstract

Some light may be shed on the transformations of demand analysis in the 1930s by telling the story of one of the period's most debated con- cepts: complementarity. What is the meaning of such sentences as "x and y are substitutes," "y and z are complementary goods," or "x and z are independent"? If x is a substitute for y, will y necessarily be a substi- tute for x? Is it supposed to have any empirical counterpart? What kind of meaning does it have in the rst place?1 All those questions emerged soon after the marginalist revolution and were given prominence in the 1930s. They were at the center of the reshaping of demand theory, toward the now-classic Hicks-Slutsky presentation of demand theory.
(This abstract was borrowed from another version of this item.)

Suggested Citation

  • Jean-Sébastien Lenfant, 2006. "Complementarity and Demand Theory: From the 1920s to the 1940s," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 38(5), pages 48-85, Supplemen.
  • Handle: RePEc:hop:hopeec:v:38:y:2006:i:5:p:48-85
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hope.dukejournals.org/content/38/Suppl_1/48.full.pdf+html
    File Function: link to full text
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to look for a different version below or search for a different version of it.

    Other versions of this item:

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Peter C. Dooley, 1983. "Slutsky's Equation is Pareto's Solution," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 15(4), pages 513-517, Winter.
    2. Louis M. Court, 1941. "Invariable Classical Stability of Entrepreneurial Demand and Supply Functions," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 56(1_Part_1), pages 134-144.
    3. Frank H. Knight, 1944. "Realism and Relevance in the Theory of Demand," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 52, pages 289-289.
    4. R. G. D. Allen, 1935. "A Note on the Determinateness of the Utility Function," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 2(2), pages 155-158.
    5. Moore, Henry Ludwell, 1914. "Economics Cycles: Their law and cause," History of Economic Thought Books, McMaster University Archive for the History of Economic Thought, number moore1914.
    6. E. J. Working, 1927. "What Do Statistical "Demand Curves" Show?," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 41(2), pages 212-235.
    7. John S. Chipman & Jean-Sébastien Lenfant, 2002. "Slutsky's 1915 Article: How It Came to Be Found and Interpreted," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 34(3), pages 553-597, Fall.
    8. Jacob L. Mosak, 1938. "Interrelations of Production, Price, and Derived Demand," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 46, pages 761-761.
    9. E. E. Lewis, 1937. "Note on Inter-Commodity Relationships in Demand," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 5(1), pages 53-59.
    10. Henry Schultz, 1927. "Mathematical Economics and the Quantitative Method," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 35, pages 702-702.
    11. Christian E. Weber, 1999. "More on Slutsky's Equation as Pareto's Solution," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 31(3), pages 575-586, Fall.
    12. Oscar Lange, 1940. "Complementarity and Interrelations of Shifts in Demand," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 8(1), pages 58-63.
    13. Wirth F. Ferger, 1932. "The Static and the Dynamic in Statistical Demand Curves," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 47(1), pages 36-62.
    14. Mordecai Ezekiel, 1927. "A Statistical Examination of Factors Related to Lamb Prices," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 35, pages 233-233.
    15. Philip Mirowski, 1990. "Problems in the Paternity of Econometrics: Henry Ludwell Moore," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 22(4), pages 587-609, Winter.
    16. Harold Hotelling, 1932. "Edgeworth's Taxation Paradox and the Nature of Demand and Supply Functions," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 40, pages 577-577.
    17. Christ, Carl F, 1985. "Early Progress in Estimating Quantitative Economic Relationships in America," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 75(6), pages 39-52, December.
    18. F. A.v. Hayek, 1943. "The Geometrical Representation of Complementarity," The Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economic Studies Ltd, vol. 10(2), pages 122-125.
    19. Elizabeth Waterman Gilboy, 1930. "Demand Curves in Theory and in Practice," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 44(4), pages 601-620.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. J.W.B. Bos & E. Stam, 2011. "Gazelles, Industry Growth and Structural Change," Working Papers 11-02, Utrecht School of Economics.
    2. Ivan Moscati, 2012. "How cardinal utility entered economic analysis during the Ordinal RevolutionLength: 31 pages," Economics and Quantitative Methods qf1205, Department of Economics, University of Insubria.
    3. M. Ali Khan & Edward E. Schlee, 2016. "On Lionel McKenzie's 1957 intrusion into 20th-century demand theory," Canadian Journal of Economics, Canadian Economics Association, vol. 49(2), pages 589-636, May.
    4. Kris De Jaegher, 2009. "Asymmetric Substitutability: Theory And Some Applications," Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International, vol. 47(4), pages 838-855, October.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. D. Wade Hands, 2012. "The Rise and Fall of Walrasian Microeconomics: The Keynesian Effect," Chapters, in: Microfoundations Reconsidered, chapter 3, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    2. Christopher L. Gilbert & Duo Qin, 2005. "The First Fifty Years of Modern Econometrics," Working Papers 544, Queen Mary University of London, School of Economics and Finance.
    3. Emeric Lendjel, 2000. "The statistical origin of the cobweb diagram," Post-Print halshs-03243880, HAL.
    4. Emeric Lendjel, 1998. "L'origine statistique du diagramme du cobweb," Working Papers halshs-00268370, HAL.
    5. Johannes Bröcker & Till Requate, 2022. "Substitution and size effect for factor demand revisited," Economic Theory Bulletin, Springer;Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory (SAET), vol. 10(2), pages 251-265, October.
    6. Emeric Lendjel, 1998. "L'origine statistique du diagramme du cobweb," Université Paris1 Panthéon-Sorbonne (Post-Print and Working Papers) halshs-00268370, HAL.
    7. Emeric Lendjel, 2000. "The statistical origin of the cobweb diagram," Université Paris1 Panthéon-Sorbonne (Post-Print and Working Papers) halshs-03243880, HAL.
    8. Jean-Sebastien Lenfant, 2012. "Indifference Curves and the Ordinalist Revolution," History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, vol. 44(1), pages 113-155, Spring.
    9. Vianna Franco, Marco P. & Ribeiro, Leonardo Costa & Albuquerque, Eduardo da Motta e, 2022. "Beyond Random Causes: Harmonic Analysis Of Business Cycles At The Moscow Conjuncture Institute," Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Cambridge University Press, vol. 44(3), pages 456-476, September.
    10. Jean-Sébastien Lenfant, 2018. "Probabilising the consumer: Georgescu-Roegen, Marschak and Quandt on the modelling of the consumer in the 1950s," The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 25(1), pages 36-72, January.
    11. Christopher L. Gilbert & Duo Qin, 2005. "The First Fifty Years of Modern Econometrics," Working Papers 544, Queen Mary University of London, School of Economics and Finance.
    12. M. Ali Khan & Edward E. Schlee, 2016. "On Lionel McKenzie's 1957 intrusion into 20th‐century demand theory," Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 49(2), pages 589-636, May.
    13. James H. Stock & Francesco Trebbi, 2003. "Retrospectives: Who Invented Instrumental Variable Regression?," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 17(3), pages 177-194, Summer.
    14. Somya Arora, 2021. "Why Are Downward-Sloping Demand Curves Unrealistic? A Critical Review of Factors Influencing Demand in More Realistic Scenario-I," Journal of Studies in Dynamics and Change (JSDC), ISSN: 2348-7038, Voices of Inclusive Change and Expressions- (VOICE) Trust, Dehradun, Uttarakhand, vol. 8(4), pages 1-16, October-D.
    15. David Teira Serrano, 2006. "A positivist tradition in early demand theory," Journal of Economic Methodology, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 13(1), pages 25-47.
    16. Ivan Moscati, 2012. "How cardinal utility entered economic analysis during the Ordinal RevolutionLength: 31 pages," Economics and Quantitative Methods qf1205, Department of Economics, University of Insubria.
    17. Alan Martina, 2000. "Antonelli's analytical techniques: their exploitation to derive results in duality theory," The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 7(3), pages 363-376.
    18. D. Wade Hands, 2010. "Henry Schultz," Chapters, in: Ross B. Emmett (ed.), The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics, chapter 15, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    19. Spanos, Aris, 1990. "The simultaneous-equations model revisited : Statistical adequacy and identification," Journal of Econometrics, Elsevier, vol. 44(1-2), pages 87-105.
    20. Spanos, Aris, 1989. "On Rereading Haavelmo: A Retrospective View of Econometric Modeling," Econometric Theory, Cambridge University Press, vol. 5(3), pages 405-429, December.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    complementarity; demand theory;

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:hop:hopeec:v:38:y:2006:i:5:p:48-85. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Center for the History of Political Economy Webmaster (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.dukeupress.edu/Catalog/ViewProduct.php?viewby=journal&productid=45614 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.