IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/agr/journl/vxxiiiy2016i2(607)p47-64.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Axiomatical examination of the neoclassical economic model. Logical assessment of the assumptions of neoclassical economic model

Author

Listed:
  • Ada MARINESCU

    (The School of Advanced Studies of the Romanian Academy, Bucharest, Romania)

Abstract

We analyze in this paper the main assumptions of the neoclassical theory, considered as axioms, like the rationality of the economic actor, equilibrium of the markets, perfect information or methodological instrumentalism. Attempts to apply to formalism in economy are related to expressing human behaviors in mathematical models and to identifying strict causalities or necessities in the structure of economic behavior. Rationality is a model which supposes that all actors act always by following the pattern of maximization and makes behavior predictable. We consider that the basic principle on which this theory is build is actually human rationality. The individual action which strictly conforms to the principles of optimizing rationality is the most primitive level from which we can deduce the whole structure of neoclassical economic theory. The neoclassical deductive system is based on the axiom of individual universal rationality. If we analyze logically this theoretical construction, we reach the conclusion that rational behavior, which means choosing based on a function of optimum, has the potential to explain all economic phenomenon, at least in an abstract and theoretical manner. It explains the behavior of an ideal agent and of an ideal economy, and its extreme generality makes it a universal principle. Correspondence with reality matters less in this strictly abstract approach compared to the possibility to build a coherent and convincing system. The proposal and axiomatic derivation of formal models was equivalent to discovering a simplified structure, obviously reductive, of the reality, but which offered through its universality the possibility of unitary interpretation of economic phenomenon. Thus the need to offer sure, stable and general foundations characterizes the neoclassical approach.

Suggested Citation

  • Ada MARINESCU, 2016. "Axiomatical examination of the neoclassical economic model. Logical assessment of the assumptions of neoclassical economic model," Theoretical and Applied Economics, Asociatia Generala a Economistilor din Romania - AGER, vol. 0(2(607), S), pages 47-64, Summer.
  • Handle: RePEc:agr:journl:v:xxiii:y:2016:i:2(607):p:47-64
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://store.ectap.ro/articole/1181.pdf
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: http://www.ectap.ro/articol.php?id=1181&rid=123
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Tony Lawson, 2013. "What is this 'school' called neoclassical economics?," Cambridge Journal of Economics, Cambridge Political Economy Society, vol. 37(5), pages 947-983.
    2. David Colander, 2018. "The Death Of Neoclassical Economics," Chapters, in: How Economics Should Be Done, chapter 5, pages 46-62, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    3. David Colander, 2009. "Complexity and the History of Economic Thought," Chapters, in: J. Barkley Rosser Jr. (ed.), Handbook of Research on Complexity, chapter 16, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    4. Friedman, Milton, 1966. "Essays in Positive Economics," University of Chicago Press Economics Books, University of Chicago Press, number 9780226264035, September.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Amitava Krishna Dutt, 2015. "Uncertainty, power, institutions, and crisis: implications for economic analysis and the future of capitalism," Review of Keynesian Economics, Edward Elgar Publishing, vol. 3(1), pages 9-28, January.
    2. Adem LEVENT, 2016. "Power, Market and Techno-Structure in John Kenneth Galbraith’s Thought," Journal of Social and Administrative Sciences, KSP Journals, vol. 3(2), pages 214-218, June.
    3. David Colander, 2000. "New Millennium Economics: How Did It Get This Way, and What Way Is It?," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 14(1), pages 121-132, Winter.
    4. Joanna Dzionek-Kozlowska, 2013. "Ekonomia jako nauka pozytywna. Refleksje na marginesie 'Ekonomii dobra i zla' Tomasa Sedlacka/Economics as a Positive Science. Reflections after Reading Thomas Sedlacek’s 'Economics of Good and Evil’," Annales. Ethics in Economic Life, University of Lodz, Faculty of Economics and Sociology, vol. 16(1), pages 335-344, May.
    5. Carlos A. Rodríguez, 2018. "Fuentes de las fluctuaciones macroeconómicas en Puerto Rico\Sources of macroeconomic fluctuations in Puerto Rico," Estudios Económicos, El Colegio de México, Centro de Estudios Económicos, vol. 33(2), pages 219-252.
    6. Karbowski, Adam, 2019. "Analiza otoczenia instytucjonalnego systemu tworzenia wiedzy w krajach Europy Środkowej [Analysis of the institutional environment of the knowledge subsystem in Central Europe]," MPRA Paper 95570, University Library of Munich, Germany, revised 2019.
    7. Jesus Munoz, 2011. "Orthodox versus Heterodox (Minskyan) Perspectives of Financial Crises: Explosion in the 1990s versus Implosion in the 2000s," Economics Working Paper Archive wp_695, Levy Economics Institute.
    8. Veneziani, Roberto & Yoshihara, Naoki, 2014. "One million miles to go: taking the axiomatic road to defining exploitation," UMASS Amherst Economics Working Papers 2014-10, University of Massachusetts Amherst, Department of Economics.
    9. Peter A. F. Fraser‐Mackenzie & Tiejun Ma & Ming‐Chien Sung & Johnnie E. V. Johnson, 2019. "Let's Call it Quits: Break‐Even Effects in the Decision to Stop Taking Risks," Risk Analysis, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 39(7), pages 1560-1581, July.
    10. Giancarlo Ianulardo & Aldo Stella, 2022. "Towards a unity of sense: A critical analysis of the concept of relation in methodological individualism and holism in Economics," The Journal of Philosophical Economics, Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies, The Journal of Philosophical Economics, vol. 15(1), pages 196-226.
    11. Millner, Antony & Ollivier, Hélène & Simon, Leo, 2014. "Policy experimentation, political competition, and heterogeneous beliefs," Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 120(C), pages 84-96.
    12. Haase, Michaela, 2020. "Considering Value-related Concepts in Service-oriented Approaches to Marketing Studies in Light of Philosophical and Economic Value Theories," SMR - Journal of Service Management Research, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft mbH & Co. KG, vol. 4(2-3), pages 133-144.
    13. Vitaliy Vasilievich Biryukov & Elena Vasilievna Romanenko, 2017. "Economic Behavior of Business Entities, Culture and Institutions: Specifics of their Interrelations in Conditions of Neo-Industrialization," European Research Studies Journal, European Research Studies Journal, vol. 0(4A), pages 370-385.
    14. Faggini, Marisa & Parziale, Anna, 2011. "Fitness landscape and tax planning: NK model for fiscal federalism," MPRA Paper 33770, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    15. Jaime Gomez-Ramirez, 2012. "Inverse Thinking in Economic Theory: A Radical Approach to Economic Thinking," Papers 1208.3460, arXiv.org.
    16. Peter Riach & Judith Rich, 1998. "Of Chicken Entrails, Anthropology, and a Realistic Social Science," Feminist Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 4(3), pages 187-191.
    17. Philip Roscoe, 2013. "On the Possibility of Organ Markets and the Performativity of Economics," Journal of Cultural Economy, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 6(4), pages 386-401, November.
    18. Victor Boussange & Didier Sornette & Heike Lischke & Loic Pellissier, 2023. "Processes analogous to ecological interactions and dispersal shape the dynamics of economic activities," Papers 2301.09486, arXiv.org.
    19. David Colander, 2018. "How Economists Got It Wrong: A Nuanced Account," Chapters, in: How Economics Should Be Done, chapter 12, pages 163-189, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    20. Sebastian Thieme, 2018. "Spiethoff's Economic Styles: a Pluralistic Approach?," Economic Thought, World Economics Association, vol. 7(1), pages 1-23, March.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:agr:journl:v:xxiii:y:2016:i:2(607):p:47-64. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Marin Dinu (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/agerrea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.